asset prices with jumps geometric brownian motion has
play

Asset prices with jumps Geometric Brownian motion has continuous - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Asset prices with jumps Geometric Brownian motion has continuous paths. Stock prices, and prices of other assets, often show jumps caused by unpredictable events or news items. So geometric Brownian motion can only be an approximation


  1. Asset prices with jumps • Geometric Brownian motion has continuous paths. • Stock prices, and prices of other assets, often show jumps caused by unpredictable events or news items. • So geometric Brownian motion can only be an approximation to the real behavior of asset prices. 1

  2. • The times at which jumps occur are often modeled by a Poisson process. • That is, if N t jumps occur in (0 , t ], then for some λ > 0 – for each s ≥ 0 and t > 0, N s + t − N s ∼ Poisson with mean λt ; – for each n ≥ 1 and times 0 ≤ t 0 ≤ · · · ≤ t n , the increments { N t r − N t r − 1 } are independent; – N 0 = 0; – N t is right-continuous in t ≥ 0. • Note the parallel with the definition of Brownian motion. 2

  3. • The parameter λ is the intensity of the process; that is, the expected number of jumps per unit time: E [ N s + t − N s ] = λ. t • If τ i is the time of the i th jump, then the inter-jump times τ 1 , τ 2 − τ 1 , τ 3 − τ 2 , . . . are independently exponentially dis- tributed with mean 1 /λ . 3

  4. • Suppose that an asset price generally follows a GBM, but each jump reduces the asset price by a fraction δ : µ − 1 �� � � 2 σ 2 (1 − δ ) N t . S t = S 0 exp t + σW t • Then S t should satisfy a differential equation like dS t = µdt + σdW t − δdN t . S t • As always, the meaning of this SDE is the corresponding stochastic integral equation � t � t � t S t − S 0 = 0 µS u du + 0 σS u dW u − 0 δS u dN u . 4

  5. • The first integral is conventional, and the second is a stochas- tic integral. • For a continuous function f , the conventional Stieltjes inte- gral is � t N t � 0 f ( u ) dN u = f ( τ i ) . i =1 • Because S t may have discontinuities at the times τ i when N t increases, the third integral is not a conventional Stieltjes integral. 5

  6. • We define it by � t N t � � � 0 f ( u, S u ) dN u = f τ i − , S τ i − . i =1 • With this definition, we have a generalized Itˆ o formula: if dY t = µ t dt + σ t dW t + ν t dN t and f is twice continuously differentiable, then � t � t 0 f ′ ( Y u − ) dY u + 1 0 f ′′ ( Y u − ) du f ( Y t ) − f ( Y 0 ) = 2 N t N t � − f f ′ � � � � � � �� � � + � Y τ i − Y τ i − Y τ i − Y τ i − f Y τ i − . i =1 i =1 6

  7. Girsanov’s Theorem with jumps • Let { W t } t ≥ 0 be a standard P -Brownian motion and { N t } t ≥ 0 a (possibly time-inhomogenous) Poisson process with intensity { λ t } t ≥ 0 under P . That is, � t M t = N t − 0 λ u du is a P -martingale. • We write F t for the σ -field generated by F W ∪ F N t . t • Suppose that { θ t } t ≥ 0 and { φ t } t ≥ 0 are {F t } t ≥ 0 -previsible pro- cesses with φ t > 0, such that � t � t 0 θ 2 s ds < ∞ and 0 φ s λ s ds < ∞ . 7

  8. • Further, let Q be the measure whose Radon-Nikodym deriva- tive with respect to P is d Q � � = L t , � d P � F t where L 0 = 1 and dL t = θ t dW t − (1 − φ t ) dM t . L t − • Then, under Q , the process { X t } t ≥ 0 defined by � t X t = W t − 0 θ s ds is a standard Brownian motion and { N t } t ≥ 0 has intensity { φ t λ t } t ≥ 0 . 8

  9. • Can we use this theorem to find an equivalent martingale measure? • Suppose again that dS t = µdt + σdW t − δdN t , S t • Then the discounted process { ˜ S t } t ≥ 0 satisfies d ˜ S t = ( µ − r ) dt + σdW t − δdN t ˜ S t = ( µ − r + σθ t − δλφ t ) dt + σdX t − δdM t . 9

  10. • Here { X t } t ≥ 0 is Q -Brownian motion, and { M t } t ≥ 0 defined by � t M t = N t − 0 λ s φ s ds is a Q -martingale. • So { ˜ S t } t ≥ 0 is a Q -martingale for any choice of { θ t } t ≥ 0 and { φ t } t ≥ 0 for which µ − r + σθ t − δλφ t = 0 . • Thus there is no unique equivalent martingale measure, and the market is incomplete: there exist F T -measurable claims C T that cannot be replicated, and cannot be hedged. 10

  11. • If we have a second asset whose price is driven by the same { W t } t ≥ 0 and { N t } t ≥ 0 , then both discounted processes become martingales under a unique Q , provided the equations µ ( i ) − r + σ ( i ) θ t − δ ( i ) λφ t = 0 , i = 1 , 2 are nonsingular for all t ≥ 0. • The extended market is therefore complete, and all claims can be replicated. 11

  12. Stochastic Volatility • The time-dependent volatility σ t may have its own dynamics: dS t = µS t dt + σ t S t dW (1) t where � � � ρdW (1) 1 − ρ 2 dW (2) σ t = a ( S t , σ t ) dt + b ( S t , σ t ) + . t t � � � � W (1) W (2) • Here and are independent Brownian t t t ≥ 0 t ≥ 0 motions, and ρ ∈ ( − 1 , 1) is the correlation between the in- crements in the two equations. 12

  13. • As in the case of jumps, equivalent martingale measures may be found but are not unique. • Again, if we have a second asset whose price is governed � � � � W (1) σ (1) by the same and , such as an option t t t ≥ 0 t ≥ 0 on S T , the extended market may have a unique equivalent martingale measure and hence be complete. 13

Recommend


More recommend