weak time derivatives and pricing equations
play

Weak time-derivatives and pricing equations Federico Severino USI - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Weak time-derivatives and pricing equations Federico Severino USI Lugano (Universit e Laval) Martingales in Finance and Physics ICTP, Trieste May 24 th , 2019 Federico Severino Weak time-derivatives and pricing 1 / 21 Plan I illustrate


  1. Weak time-derivatives and pricing equations Federico Severino USI Lugano (Universit´ e Laval) Martingales in Finance and Physics ICTP, Trieste May 24 th , 2019 Federico Severino Weak time-derivatives and pricing 1 / 21

  2. Plan I illustrate a novel mathematical tool for the characterization of martingales in continuous time: the weak time-derivative of Marinacci, Severino ( Finance & Stochastics , 2018). I compare weak time-differentiability with other existing notions (infinitesimal generator). I discuss some fundamental asset pricing equations related to martingale identification. I present some measure changes that originate useful martingale processes for pricing. Federico Severino Weak time-derivatives and pricing 2 / 21

  3. General set-up Time interval [ 0, T ] . Filtered probability space ( Ω , F , F , P ) . U is the space of adapted processes u : [ 0, T ] → L 1 ( F T ) that ◮ are L 1 -right-continuous in [ 0, T ) , ◮ are L 1 -left-continuous at T , ◮ have finite � T 0 E [ | u τ | ] d τ . Martingales belong to U . Federico Severino Weak time-derivatives and pricing 3 / 21

  4. Weak time-differentiability Definition A process u ∈ U is weakly time-differentiable when there exists a process D u ∈ U such that, for every t ∈ [ 0, T ] , � T � T E [ u τ 1 A t ] ϕ ′ ( τ ) d τ E [( D u ) τ 1 A t ] ϕ ( τ ) d τ = − t t for all A t ∈ F t and ϕ ∈ C 1 c ([ t , T ]) . D u is the weak time-derivative of u . A bridge between variational and stochastic calculus. Purpose: capture the behaviour of the conditional expectation over time. Federico Severino Weak time-derivatives and pricing 4 / 21

  5. Martingales via weak time-derivatives U 1 denotes the space of weakly time-differentiable processes u ∈ U . Proposition u belongs to U 1 and has D u = 0 if and only if u is a martingale. Proposition Let u ∈ U 1 . Then, D u � 0 if and only if u is a submartingale. D u � 0 if and only if u is a supermartingale. Federico Severino Weak time-derivatives and pricing 5 / 21

  6. Properties of weak time-derivatives Proposition Consider g ∈ U , m a martingale and � t u t = 0 g s ds + m t , Then, D u = g . Federico Severino Weak time-derivatives and pricing 6 / 21

  7. Examples: deterministic drift + martingale Consider α ∈ R and m a martingale. Then, u t = α t + m t has D u = α . E.g. in Black-Scholes (1973) log prices satisfy log ( X t ) = ( r − σ 2 / 2 ) t + σ W Q t , where W Q is a Wiener process under the risk-neutral measure Q . Then, D ( log X ) = r − σ 2 / 2 . Federico Severino Weak time-derivatives and pricing 7 / 21

  8. Examples: continuous Itˆ o semimartingales Consider g ∈ U , h adapted and � T 0 E [ h 2 s ] ds finite. Then, the process X ∈ U defined by dX t = g t dt + h t dW t has D X = g . The weak time-derivative is the drift. If u t = f ( t , X t ) with f regular, then by Itˆ o’s formula 2 h 2 ∂ 2 f ∂ t + 1 D u = g ∂ f ∂ x + ∂ f ∂ x 2 . Federico Severino Weak time-derivatives and pricing 8 / 21

  9. Characterization of weak time-differentiable processes Theorem u ∈ U is weakly time-differentiable if and only if it is a special martingale u = a + m , with a t = � t 0 ( D u ) s ds and m a martingale. U 1 is the space of special semimartingales that feature a (unique) absolutely continuous finite variation term and a (unique) local martingale term which is actually a martingale. Federico Severino Weak time-derivatives and pricing 9 / 21

  10. Example: jump-diffusion processes Consider dX t X t − = µ dt + σ dW t + dH t , where H is a compound Poisson process: H t = ∑ N t k = 1 z k , where ◮ N is a Poisson process independent of W with intensity λ , ◮ z k are i.i.d., independent of W and N , ◮ E [ z k ] = z , ◮ z k � − 1. The compensated Poisson process ˆ H t = H t − λ zt is a martingale. Hence, dX t X t − = ( µ + λ z ) dt + σ dW t + d ˆ H t has D X t = ( µ + λ z ) X t − Federico Severino Weak time-derivatives and pricing 10 / 21

  11. Infinitesimal generator Let X be a Feller process. The infinitesimal generator A maps any continuous bounded function f belonging to dom( A ) into the function A f such that E t [ f ( X t + h )] − f ( X t ) A f ( X t ) = lim ∀ t ∈ [ 0, T ] . h h → 0 + The limit is in the uniform topology over all states ω ∈ Ω and A f is continuous and bounded. The weak time-derivative coincides with the infinitesimal generator. Federico Severino Weak time-derivatives and pricing 11 / 21

  12. Extended infinitesimal generator Let X be a Markov process. The extended infinitesimal generator of a measurable function f of X t is a measurable function g such that g ( X t ) is integrable and the process � t z t = f ( X t ) − f ( X 0 ) − 0 g ( X τ ) d τ is a martingale. The weak time-derivative coincides with the extended infinitesimal generator. Federico Severino Weak time-derivatives and pricing 12 / 21

  13. No arbitrage pricing Consider an arbitrage-free market with constant interest rate r , several risky securities and a bond. The value B t = e rt of the bond satisfies dB t = rB t dt t ∈ [ 0, T ) . P is the given (physical) measure. Q is a risk-neutral measure that makes discounted prices Q -martingales. Federico Severino Weak time-derivatives and pricing 13 / 21

  14. Weak time-derivatives and no arbitrage pricing Consider the price π of a marketed payoff h T ∈ L 1 ( F T , Q ) . Proposition Under Q the following conditions are equivalent: ( i ) π is a no arbitrage price process; ( ii ) D ( π / B ) = 0; ( iii ) D π = r π . D π = r π generalizes the bond equation to random payoffs. Federico Severino Weak time-derivatives and pricing 14 / 21

  15. The no arbitrage pricing equation Theorem Under Q there exists a unique solution π in U 1 of � ( D π ) t = r π t t ∈ [ 0, T ) π T = h T given by π t = e − r ( T − t ) E Q t [ h T ] . The proof exploits the martingale property of π / B under Q . Federico Severino Weak time-derivatives and pricing 15 / 21

  16. Example: Black-Scholes model Under P the bond and the risky asset follow: dX t = µ X t dt + σ X t dW P dB t = rB t dt , t . Under Q the two securities share the same drift coefficient r : dX t = rX t dt + σ X t dW Q dB t = rB t dt , t . The no arbitrage pricing equation captures the drift change due to risk-neutrality. Federico Severino Weak time-derivatives and pricing 16 / 21

  17. Risk neutrality and discounting The usefulness of martingales goes beyond discounted prices under Q . Indeed, different ways of discounting originate different martingales. E.g., if interest rates are stochastics (and denoted by r t ), the previous bond can be replaced ◮ by the money market account with ⋆ value 1 at time 0 � T 0 r τ d τ at time T ⋆ value e ◮ or by the zero-coupon bond with ⋆ value 1 at time T ⋆ value E Q [ e − � T 0 r τ d τ ] at time 0. Federico Severino Weak time-derivatives and pricing 17 / 21

  18. The forward measure The measure Q corresponds to discounting by the money market account. Discounting by zero-coupon bonds generates the forward measure F , which is still an equivalent martingale measure. Drifts of prices under different measures may be very different, although drifts of discounted prices are null. Suppose that dr t = µ ( t , r t ) dt + σ ( t , r t ) dW P t . E.g. r t follows a Vasicek (1977), or Ornstein-Uhlenbeck, process. Federico Severino Weak time-derivatives and pricing 18 / 21

  19. Example: dynamics of zero-coupon bond prices π t ( 1 T ) By Itˆ o’s formula, the zero-coupon bond price satisfies under P d π t ( 1 T ) σ ( t , r t ) dW P π t ( 1 T ) = � µ ( t , r t ) dt + � t . Under Q the same price follows d π t ( 1 T ) σ ( t , r t ) dW Q π t ( 1 T ) = r t dt + � t . Under F the dynamics is � � d π t ( 1 T ) σ 2 ( t , r t ) σ ( t , r t ) dW F π t ( 1 T ) = r t + � dt + � t . See further details and examples in Severino (2019). Federico Severino Weak time-derivatives and pricing 19 / 21

  20. Changes of num´ eraires and martingales Martingales under the forward measure are very important: they identify forward prices . Forward prices are related to contracts that fix a price at time 0 for delivering a commodity/payoff at time T . Differential tools that are able to characterize martingales may be useful for studying these objects. Moreover, many changes of num´ eraires (and the related martingales) are illustrated in the option pricing literature, in very diverse contexts. Federico Severino Weak time-derivatives and pricing 20 / 21

  21. Conclusions The weak time-derivative captures the drift of semimartingale processes and provides a characterization of martingales. The no arbitrage pricing equation for random payoffs exploits the martingale property of discounted prices. Alternative discounting ways (together with suitable measure changes) deliver different martingales associated to asset prices. Thank you for your attention! Federico Severino Weak time-derivatives and pricing 21 / 21

Recommend


More recommend