quadratic and superquadratic bsdes and related pdes
play

Quadratic and Superquadratic BSDEs and Related PDEs Ying Hu IRMAR, - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Quadratic and Superquadratic BSDEs and Related PDEs Ying Hu IRMAR, Universit Rennes 1, FRANCE http://perso.univ-rennes1.fr/ying.hu/ ITN Marie Curie Workshop "Stochastic Control and Finance" Roscoff, March 2010 Ying Hu, Univ.


  1. Quadratic and Superquadratic BSDEs and Related PDEs Ying Hu IRMAR, Université Rennes 1, FRANCE http://perso.univ-rennes1.fr/ying.hu/ ITN Marie Curie Workshop "Stochastic Control and Finance" Roscoff, March 2010 Ying Hu, Univ. Rennes 1 Quadratic and Superquadratic BSDEs Roscoff, March 2010 1/43

  2. I. Utility maximization The financial market consists of one bond with interest rate zero and d ≤ m stocks. In case d < m we face an incomplete market. The price process of stock i evolves according to the equation dS i t = b i t dt + σ i t dB t , i = 1 , . . . , d , (1) S i t where b i (resp. σ i ) is a R – valued (resp. R 1 × m –valued) stochastic process. The lines of the d × m –matrix σ are given by the vector σ i t , i = 1 , . . . , d . The volatility matrix σ = ( σ i ) i = 1 ,..., d has full rank ( i.e. σσ tr is invertible P -a.s. ) The predictable R m –valued process ( called the risk premium ) is defined by: θ t = σ tr t ( σ t σ tr t ) − 1 b t , t ∈ [ 0 , T ] . A d –dimensional F t –predictable process π = ( π t ) 0 ≤ t ≤ T is called trading � � T π dS 0 � π t σ t � 2 dt < ∞ P–a.s. For 1 ≤ i ≤ d , strategy if S is well defined, e.g. the process π i t describes the amount of money invested in stock i at time t . The number of shares is π i t . t S i Ying Hu, Univ. Rennes 1 Quadratic and Superquadratic BSDEs Roscoff, March 2010 2/43

  3. The wealth process X π of a trading strategy π with initial capital x satisfies the equation � t � t � d π i , u X π t = x + dS i , u = x + π u σ u ( dB u + θ u du ) . S i , u 0 0 i = 1 Suppose our investor has a liability F at time T . Let us recall that for α > 0 the exponential utility function is defined as U ( x ) = − exp ( − α x ) , x ∈ R . We allow constraints on the trading strategies. Formally, they are supposed to take their values in a closed set, i.e. π t ( ω ) ∈ C , with C ⊆ R 1 × d , and 0 ∈ C . Ying Hu, Univ. Rennes 1 Quadratic and Superquadratic BSDEs Roscoff, March 2010 3/43

  4. Definition [ Admissible Strategies with constraints ] Let C be a closed set in R 1 × d and 0 ∈ C . The set of admissible trading strategies A D consists of all d –dimensional predictable processes π = ( π t ) 0 ≤ t ≤ T which satisfy � T 0 | π t σ t | 2 dt < ∞ and π t ∈ C P -a.s., as well as { exp ( − α X π τ ) : τ stopping time with values in [ 0 , T ] } is a uniformly integrable family. So the investor wants to solve the maximization problem � � � ��� � T dS t V ( x ) := sup E − exp − α x + − F (2) π t , S t π ∈A D 0 where x is the initial wealth. V is called value function. Ying Hu, Univ. Rennes 1 Quadratic and Superquadratic BSDEs Roscoff, March 2010 4/43

  5. This problem has been studied by many authors, but they suppose that the constraint is convex in order to apply convex duality. Our starting point of the work is the paper [Hu-Imkeller-Muller, AAP 2005] where both the risk premium θ and the liability F are bounded. The main method can be described as follows. In order to find the value function and an optimal strategy one constructs a family of stochastic processes R ( π ) with the following properties: • R ( π ) = − exp ( − α ( X π T − F )) for all π ∈ A D ; T • R ( π ) = R 0 is constant for all π ∈ A D ; 0 • R ( π ) is a supermartingale for all π ∈ A D and there exists a π ∗ ∈ A D such that R ( π ∗ ) is a martingale. The process R ( π ) and its initial value R 0 depend of course on the initial capital x . Ying Hu, Univ. Rennes 1 Quadratic and Superquadratic BSDEs Roscoff, March 2010 5/43

  6. Given processes possessing these properties we can compare the expected utilities of the strategies π ∈ A D and π ∗ ∈ A D by E [ − exp ( − α ( X π T − F ))] ≤ R 0 ( x ) = E [ − exp ( − α ( X π ∗ T − F ))] = V ( x ) , (3) whence π ∗ is the desired optimal strategy. Construction of R ( π ) : R ( π ) := − exp ( − α ( X ( π ) − Y t )) , t ∈ [ 0 , T ] , π ∈ A D , t t where ( Y , Z ) is a solution of the BSDE � T � T Y t = F − Z s dB s + f ( s , Z s ) ds , t ∈ [ 0 , T ] . t t In these terms one is bound to choose a function f for which R ( π ) is a supermartingale for all π ∈ A D and there exists a π ∗ ∈ A D such that R ( π ∗ ) is a martingale. This function f also depends on the constraint set ( C ) where ( π t ) takes its values. One gets then V ( x ) = R ( π, x ) = − exp ( − α ( x − Y 0 )) , for all π ∈ A D . 0 Ying Hu, Univ. Rennes 1 Quadratic and Superquadratic BSDEs Roscoff, March 2010 6/43

  7. In order to satisfy the supermartingale and the martingale properties, one finds f ( t , z ) = α π ∈C | πσ − ( z + 1 αθ t ) | 2 − z θ t − 1 2 α | θ t | 2 . 2 min The function f is well defined because it only depends on the distance between a point and a closed set. Important: the generator f is of quadratic growth with respect to z ! Ying Hu, Univ. Rennes 1 Quadratic and Superquadratic BSDEs Roscoff, March 2010 7/43

  8. Lemma Suppose that both the risk premium θ and the liability F are bounded. Then, the value function of the optimization problem (2) is given by V ( x ) = − exp ( − α ( x − Y 0 )) , where Y 0 is defined by the unique solution ( Y , Z ) of the BSDE � T � T Y t = F − Z s dB s + f ( s , Z s ) ds , t ∈ [ 0 , T ] , (4) t t with π ∈C | πσ − ( z + 1 αθ ) | 2 − z θ − 1 f ( · , z ) = α 2 α | θ | 2 . 2 min There exists an optimal trading strategy π ∗ ∈ A D with t ∈ argmin {| πσ − ( Z t + 1 π ∗ αθ t ) | , π ∈ C} , t ∈ [ 0 , T ] , P − a . s . (5) Ying Hu, Univ. Rennes 1 Quadratic and Superquadratic BSDEs Roscoff, March 2010 8/43

  9. II. Dynamic g Risk Measures (Barrieu-El Karoui, arXiv 2007) Definition Assume that ( ξ T , g ) satisfies: (1) g is a P × B ( R ) × B ( R d ) -measurable generator satisfying z → g ( t , z ) is convex, and | g ( t , z ) | ≤ | g ( t , 0 ) | + k 1 2 | z | 2 , 2 ∈ M ; | g ( t , 0 ) | (2) ξ T is an F T -measurable bounded random variable. Define R g ( ξ T ) as the unique solution of the BSDE ( − ξ T , g ) . Proposition (Barrieu-El Karoui) R g is a dynamic risk measure. Ying Hu, Univ. Rennes 1 Quadratic and Superquadratic BSDEs Roscoff, March 2010 9/43

  10. Inf-convolution In the case of bounded ξ , B-E established Proposition R g A � g B ( ξ T ) t = R g A � R g B ( ξ T ) t . Ying Hu, Univ. Rennes 1 Quadratic and Superquadratic BSDEs Roscoff, March 2010 10/43

  11. Backward Stochastic Differential Equation � T � T Y t = ξ + f ( s , Y s , Z s ) ds − Z s dB s (E ξ, f ) t t • ξ is the terminal value : F T –measurable • f is the generator • ( Y , Z ) is the unknown • ( Y , Z ) has to be adapted to F Pardoux–Peng, ’90 If f is Lipschitz w.r.t. ( y , z ) and � � � T | ξ | 2 + | f ( s , 0 , 0 ) | 2 ds < + ∞ E 0 (E ξ, f ) has a unique square integrable solution. Ying Hu, Univ. Rennes 1 Quadratic and Superquadratic BSDEs Roscoff, March 2010 11/43

  12. Nonlinear Feynman-Kac Formula Semilinear PDE (P) ∂ t u ( t , x ) + L u ( t , x ) + f ( t , x , u ( t , x ) , ( ∇ x u ) tr σ ( t , x )) = 0 , u ( T , . ) = g , L u ( t , x ) = 1 2trace ( σσ ∗ ∇ 2 x u ( t , x )) + b ( t , x ) · ∇ x u ( t , x ) . Linear part = ⇒ SDE � t � t � � � � X t 0 , x 0 s , X t 0 , x 0 s , X t 0 , x 0 = x 0 + b ds + σ dB s t s s t 0 t 0 Nonlinear part = BSDE (B) ⇒ � T � T � � � � Y t 0 , x 0 X t 0 , x 0 s , X t 0 , x 0 , Y t 0 , x 0 , Z t 0 , x 0 Z t 0 , x 0 = g + f ds − dB s t T s s s s t t Ying Hu, Univ. Rennes 1 Quadratic and Superquadratic BSDEs Roscoff, March 2010 12/43

  13. Nonlinear Feynman-Kac Formula If u is smooth solution to (P) � � � � �� t , X t 0 , x 0 t , X t 0 , x 0 , ( ∇ x u ) tr σ u solves the BSDE (B) t t Feynman-Kac’s Formula u ( t , x ) := Y t , x is a (viscosity) solution to (P). t Ying Hu, Univ. Rennes 1 Quadratic and Superquadratic BSDEs Roscoff, March 2010 13/43

  14. Quadratic BSDEs A real valued BSDE � T � T Y t = ξ + f ( s , Y s , Z s ) ds − Z s dB s (E ξ, f ) t t • B is a Brownian motion in R d ; • ξ is F T –measurable; • the generator f : [ 0 , T ] × Ω × R × R d − → R is measurable and • ( y , z ) �− → f ( t , y , z ) is continuous • f is quadratic with respect to z : | f ( t , y , z ) | ≤ α ( t ) + β | y | + γ 2 | z | 2 where β ≥ 0, γ > 0 and α is a nonnegative process. Ying Hu, Univ. Rennes 1 Quadratic and Superquadratic BSDEs Roscoff, March 2010 14/43

  15. The bounded case � T If ξ and α – or more generally | α | 1 := α ( s ) ds – are bounded 0 • Existence • Uniqueness, Comparison Theorem • Stability References: • M. Kobylanski (AP 2000); • M.-A. Morlais (non Brownian setting, Ph. D 2007) These results yield The Nonlinear Feynman-Kac Formula Ying Hu, Univ. Rennes 1 Quadratic and Superquadratic BSDEs Roscoff, March 2010 15/43

  16. Applications of bounded case • Utility maximization: El Karoui & Rouge (MF 2000), Hu, Imkeller & Muller (AAP 2005) (with closed constraint), Mania & Schweizer (AAP 2005), Becherer (AAP 2006), Morlais (Ph D 2007) • Stochastic linear quadratic control: Bismut (1970-1979), Peng, Kohlman & Tang, Hu & Zhou (with cone constraint SICON 2005), Schweizer et al. • Quadratic g risk measure: Barrieu & El Karoui Ying Hu, Univ. Rennes 1 Quadratic and Superquadratic BSDEs Roscoff, March 2010 16/43

Recommend


More recommend