MONTHLY AND QUARTERLY GDP ESTIMATES FOR INTERWAR BRITAIN James Mitchell (NIESR) Solomos Solomou (Cambridge) National Institute of Economic and Martin Weale (BOE and NIESR) Social Research
Monthly GDP estimates • Derive monthly series of UK GDP for the inter-war period from a set of monthly indicators that were constructed at the time • Illustrate how the new data can contribute to our understanding of the economic history of the UK in the 1930s • Use the series to draw comparisons between recession profiles in the 1930s and the post- war period
Monthly indicators of economic activity • Work by Burns and Mitchell (1946) anticipated by The Economist • The Economist collected monthly indicators during the period 1924-1938 and published an aggregate indicator computed as the geometric mean of the indicators • These data form the basis of our monthly GDP indicator, together with data for quarterly industrial production
Need for monthly GDP estimates • GDP is the most appropriate indicator of overall economic activity • Preferable to relate these new (or lost) The Economist data directly to GDP • Avoids subjective inference based on simply eye- balling these data - or averaging them • Unlike Rhodes (1937, JRSS) and Stock & Watson (2002, JBES) we reduce these monthly data to an estimator of monthly GDP itself • This involves exploiting available annual GDP data for the interwar period (1924-1938) • Monthly GDP data facilitate historical analysis
Monthly indicators of economic activity • Averaging the indicator variables is not the only method of aggregation • Rhodes (1937, JRSS) – anticipating Stock & Watson (2002, JBES) - suggested instead use of the first principal component of the series • But it is not necessarily the aggregate that is most closely correlated with GDP growth • Some means is needed of selecting from the indicators a composite which is closely linked to GDP rather than one which is simply a summary of the indicator data set • And this must be consistent with the annual GDP data • We derive monthly GDP series exploiting these new monthly data from The Economist and quarterly industrial production
Interpolating GDP using monthly indicators • Chow-Lin (1971, ReStat). Dynamics ad hoc • Dynamic generalisations – accommodate dynamics flexibly via AR polynomial • Model data in logarithms – Implies a nonlinear temporal aggregation constraint • Regression based methods – Mitchell et al. (2005, EJ) • State-space methods – Harvey & Pierse (1984, JASA) – Multivariate extensions: Moauro & Savio (2005, EcsJ) • Dynamic factor model. Useful when N gets big(ish)
Interpolating monthly GDP using a dynamic factor model • Based on Proietti and Moauro (2006, JRSSC) • Work in log-levels rather than growth rates as in Stock and Watson (1991) – Mariano & Murasawa (2003, JAE) - and can handle mixed frequency data • Assumes a latent factor, the business cycle , drives (co)variation in the observed mixed-frequency data – Consistent with Burns and Mitchell’s (1946) characterisation of the business cycle as common movements in different economic indicators – Stone (1947, JRSS) and Stock & Watson (1991) • Provides exact solution to nonlinearity of aggregation constraint
Interpolating monthly GDP using a dynamic factor model y • Model monthly N -vector in levels rather than t m , first differences ⎫ y θ μ * = µ + = = , t 1,..., ; T m 1,...,12 ⎪ t m , t m , t m , ⎪ 2 ⎬ φ Δ µ = η η ∼ σ ( ) L , NID (0, ) η t m , t m , t m , ⎪ D μ β η η 0 Σ * * * Δ = + ∼ ( ) L , NID ( , ) ⎪ ⎭ * t m , t m , t m , η µ • The common trend and the idiosyncratic t m , μ * components are modelled as difference t m , stationary processes Δ β • ( i=1,…,N ) is composed of drift , an y it m , i − 1 * η individual AR plus the business cycle d L ( ) i it m , − 1 φ η ( ) L (common) AR component t m , – This flexibility means the model fits the data
Estimation with constraints • Identification • Estimation by ML exploiting Kalman filter • Partition data vector into y y = ( ' , y , y )' t m , 1 , t m 2 , t m 3 , t m • where y 1t,m represents the observed monthly indicators from The Economist and y 2t,m and y 3t,m are monthly IP and GDP which are latent and the objects we wish to estimate • We observe annual GDP data y 3t such that = ∑ 12 y y 3 t 3 , t m = m 1 • Similarly define a constraint given quarterly IP data – Impose constraints by defining a cumulator variable
The Economist ’s monthly data
Monthly GDP 1924 - 1938 • We present data at both market prices and factor cost, but focus attention on the market price data • Model subjected to diagnostic tests • We could not accept the restriction that the idiosyncratic components shared a common AR coefficient • The factor loadings are all positive and are mostly significantly different from zero at 5% – T he Economist ’s series are coincident indicators of economic activity – Employment, cotton, IP and GDP most sensitive to the business cycle
£mn 1938 prices Factor Cost Monthly GDP at 1938 Market Prices and 250 300 350 400 450 500 1924-1 1924-7 1925-1 1925-7 1926-1 1926-7 1927-1 1927-7 1928-1 1928-7 1929-1 Market prices 1929-7 1930-1 1930-7 1931-1 1931-7 1932-1 Factor cost 1932-7 1933-1 1933-7 1934-1 1934-7 1935-1 1935-7 1936-1 1936-7 1937-1 1937-7 1938-1 1938-7
Historical analysis of the Great Depression • Burns and Mitchell (1946) dated peak at July 1929 • Our GDP data suggest Jan 1930 • They dated the recovery from Aug 1932 • We see no sustained recovery until well into 1933 • These apparently minor differences can have substantial implications – Say if we wish to address the role of particular policies (e.g. devaluation in Sept 1931; monetary expansion in April 1932) in generating recovery – The role of policy change in generating expectational changes – Sargent (1983) and Temin (1989) – Previously absence of British data prevented analysis – Our data indicate a “hesitant recovery path” consistent with the view that the policymakers found it hard to generate a favourable expectational change with a single policy move
The Profiles of Five UK Depressions The postwar monthly GDP data are from 2% NIESR; see Mitchell et al. (2005, EJ) 1% 0% GDP : Change from Peak -1% -2% -3% -4% -5% -6% -7% -8% -9% 0 6 12 18 24 30 36 42 48 Months from Start of Recession 1930-1934 1973-1976 1979-1983 1990-1993 2008-
Conclusion • Rather than use disparate indicators in an ad hoc manner to draw conclusions about the profiles of business cycles, it is preferable to use these variables to construct high- frequency estimates of GDP itself • The high frequency GDP data we provide are, we hope, of use to economists and economic historians addressing a number of questions • The global financial crisis of 2008 has resulted in renewed interest in the homologies between the current events and the Great Depression • But to-date (Eichengreen and O’Rourke, 2009) use has only been made of lower frequency GDP or IP data
Recommend
More recommend