exponentially concave functions and multiplicative
play

Exponentially concave functions and multiplicative cyclical - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Exponentially concave functions and multiplicative cyclical monotonicity W. Schachermayer University of Vienna Faculty of Mathematics 11th December, RICAM, Linz Based on the paper S. Pal, T.L. Wong: The Geometry of relative arbitrage.


  1. Exponentially concave functions and multiplicative cyclical monotonicity W. Schachermayer University of Vienna Faculty of Mathematics 11th December, RICAM, Linz Based on the paper S. Pal, T.L. Wong: The Geometry of relative arbitrage. (ArXiv:1402.3720)

  2. Exponential concavity Fix a convex subset U ⊆ R n . Typically U will equal the unit simplex n ∆ n = { ( p 1 , . . . , p n ) ∈ [0 , 1] n : � p i = 1 } i =1 or a convex subset of ∆ n , e.g. int (∆ n ) . Definition: A function ϕ : U �→ R is called exponentially concave if Φ = exp( ϕ ) is a concave function. An exponentially concave function is concave but not vice versa. For example, consider U = (0 , 1) . An affine function ϕ ( x ) = ax + b on U is concave but not exponentially concave. On the other hand, the function ϕ ( x ) = log( x ) is the arch-example of an exponentially concave function on U .

  3. Exponential concavity Fix a convex subset U ⊆ R n . Typically U will equal the unit simplex n ∆ n = { ( p 1 , . . . , p n ) ∈ [0 , 1] n : � p i = 1 } i =1 or a convex subset of ∆ n , e.g. int (∆ n ) . Definition: A function ϕ : U �→ R is called exponentially concave if Φ = exp( ϕ ) is a concave function. An exponentially concave function is concave but not vice versa. For example, consider U = (0 , 1) . An affine function ϕ ( x ) = ax + b on U is concave but not exponentially concave. On the other hand, the function ϕ ( x ) = log( x ) is the arch-example of an exponentially concave function on U .

  4. Exponential concavity Fix a convex subset U ⊆ R n . Typically U will equal the unit simplex n ∆ n = { ( p 1 , . . . , p n ) ∈ [0 , 1] n : � p i = 1 } i =1 or a convex subset of ∆ n , e.g. int (∆ n ) . Definition: A function ϕ : U �→ R is called exponentially concave if Φ = exp( ϕ ) is a concave function. An exponentially concave function is concave but not vice versa. For example, consider U = (0 , 1) . An affine function ϕ ( x ) = ax + b on U is concave but not exponentially concave. On the other hand, the function ϕ ( x ) = log( x ) is the arch-example of an exponentially concave function on U .

  5. Lemma: Let U be a convex subset of R n . A concave function ϕ : U �→ R is exponentially concave iff for every µ 0 , µ 1 ∈ U the function f ( t ) = ϕ ( t µ 0 + (1 − t ) µ 1 ) satisfies f ′′ ( t ) ≤ − ( f ′ ( t )) 2 , for almost all t in [0 , 1] . Indeed, for F ( t ) = exp( f ( t )) we have F ′′ ( t ) = F ( t )[ f ′′ ( t ) + ( f ′ ( t )) 2 ] .

  6. Lemma: Let U be a convex subset of R n . A concave function ϕ : U �→ R is exponentially concave iff for every µ 0 , µ 1 ∈ U the function f ( t ) = ϕ ( t µ 0 + (1 − t ) µ 1 ) satisfies f ′′ ( t ) ≤ − ( f ′ ( t )) 2 , for almost all t in [0 , 1] . Indeed, for F ( t ) = exp( f ( t )) we have F ′′ ( t ) = F ( t )[ f ′′ ( t ) + ( f ′ ( t )) 2 ] .

  7. Definition: Let U ⊆ R n and T : U �→ R n a (possibly multi-valued) map (interpreted as a transport map). We call T multiplicatively cyclically monotone if, for all µ 1 , . . . , µ m , µ m +1 = µ 1 ∈ U and all values T ( µ 1 ) , . . . , T ( µ m ) we have � T ( µ j ) , µ j +1 − µ j � > − 1 and m � (1 + � T ( µ j ) , µ j +1 − µ j � ) ≥ 1 , (1) j =1 or, equivalently � n log(1 + � T ( µ j ) , µ j +1 − µ j � ) ≥ 0 . (2) j =1 Recall that T is cyclically monotone if n � � T ( µ j ) , µ j +1 − µ j � ≥ 0 . (3) j =1

  8. Theorem [PW14]: Let U ⊆ R n be a convex set and ϕ : U �→ R a concave function. Then ϕ is exponentially concave iff its super-differential T := ∂ϕ on U is multiplicatively cyclically monotone. In this case, ϕ is unique up to an additive constant. Sketch of proof Assume that ϕ is exponentially concave so that Φ( µ ) = exp( ϕ ( µ )) is a concave function on U . Denote by S ( µ ) the super-differential of Φ for which we have Φ( µ j +1 ) ≤ Φ( µ j ) + � S ( µ j ) , µ j +1 − µ j � , or � S ( µ j ) Φ( µ j ) , µ j +1 − µ j � Φ( µ j +1 ) ≤ 1 + . Φ( µ j )

  9. Theorem [PW14]: Let U ⊆ R n be a convex set and ϕ : U �→ R a concave function. Then ϕ is exponentially concave iff its super-differential T := ∂ϕ on U is multiplicatively cyclically monotone. In this case, ϕ is unique up to an additive constant. Sketch of proof Assume that ϕ is exponentially concave so that Φ( µ ) = exp( ϕ ( µ )) is a concave function on U . Denote by S ( µ ) the super-differential of Φ for which we have Φ( µ j +1 ) ≤ Φ( µ j ) + � S ( µ j ) , µ j +1 − µ j � , or � S ( µ j ) Φ( µ j ) , µ j +1 − µ j � Φ( µ j +1 ) ≤ 1 + . Φ( µ j )

  10. Sketch of proof contd. Assuming that Φ is differentiable, the super-differential S ( µ ) equals ∇ Φ( µ ) so that T := ∇ ϕ = ∇ (log(Φ) = ∇ Φ Φ = S Φ . Therefore Φ( µ j +1 ) ≤ 1 + � T ( µ j ) , µ j +1 − µ j � . Φ( µ j ) If µ 1 , µ 2 , . . . , µ m , µ m +1 = µ 1 is a roundtrip we have � m 1 = Φ( µ m +1 ) (1 + � T ( µ j ) , µ j +1 − µ j � ) . ≤ Φ( µ 1 ) i =1 Hence T is multiplicatively cyclically monotone.

  11. Applications in Finance Relative Capital distribution 1929-1999 of NY stock exchange:

  12. Stochastic portfolio Theory R. Fernholz (1999), Karatzas & Fernholz (2009), . . . We consider n stocks with relative market capitalization at time t µ ( t ) = ( µ 1 ( t ) , . . . , µ n ( t )) ∈ int (∆ n ) . A portfolio is a map π : int (∆ n ) �→ ∆ n . Interpretation: The agent invests her wealth V ( t ) according to π ( µ ( t )) during ] t , t + 1] . We associate to π the weights w ( µ ) = ( π 1 ( µ ) , . . . , π n ( µ ) ) ∈ R n + . µ 1 µ n

  13. Stochastic portfolio Theory R. Fernholz (1999), Karatzas & Fernholz (2009), . . . We consider n stocks with relative market capitalization at time t µ ( t ) = ( µ 1 ( t ) , . . . , µ n ( t )) ∈ int (∆ n ) . A portfolio is a map π : int (∆ n ) �→ ∆ n . Interpretation: The agent invests her wealth V ( t ) according to π ( µ ( t )) during ] t , t + 1] . We associate to π the weights w ( µ ) = ( π 1 ( µ ) , . . . , π n ( µ ) ) ∈ R n + . µ 1 µ n

  14. Example: a) the market portfolio : π ( µ ) = µ w ( µ ) = (1 , . . . , 1) b) The equal weight portfolio : π ( µ ) = (1 n , . . . , 1 w ( µ ) = 1 n ( 1 , . . . , 1 n ) ) µ 1 µ n c) Let 0 < p < 1 and � � � � µ p − 1 µ p µ p µ p − 1 1 n 1 n � n � n π ( µ ) = , . . . , , w ( µ ) = � n , . . . , � n i =1 µ p i =1 µ p 1 i =1 µ p 1 i =1 µ p i i i i p p

  15. Example: a) the market portfolio : π ( µ ) = µ w ( µ ) = (1 , . . . , 1) b) The equal weight portfolio : π ( µ ) = (1 n , . . . , 1 w ( µ ) = 1 n ( 1 , . . . , 1 n ) ) µ 1 µ n c) Let 0 < p < 1 and � � � � µ p − 1 µ p µ p µ p − 1 1 n 1 n � n � n π ( µ ) = , . . . , , w ( µ ) = � n , . . . , � n i =1 µ p i =1 µ p 1 i =1 µ p 1 i =1 µ p i i i i p p

  16. Example: a) the market portfolio : π ( µ ) = µ w ( µ ) = (1 , . . . , 1) b) The equal weight portfolio : π ( µ ) = (1 n , . . . , 1 w ( µ ) = 1 n ( 1 , . . . , 1 n ) ) µ 1 µ n c) Let 0 < p < 1 and � � � � µ p − 1 µ p µ p µ p − 1 1 n 1 n � n � n π ( µ ) = , . . . , , w ( µ ) = � n , . . . , � n i =1 µ p i =1 µ p 1 i =1 µ p 1 i =1 µ p i i i i p p

  17. Question: Can you beat the market portfolio ? Given the portfolio map π : int (∆ n ) �→ ∆ n and a sequence ( µ ( t )) m t =1 , we obtain for the relative wealth (in terms of the market portfolio) n � V ( t + 1) µ i ( t + 1) = π i ( µ ( t )) V ( t ) µ i ( t ) i =1 � n = w i ( µ ( t )) µ i ( t + 1) . i =1 = � w ( µ ( t )) , µ ( t + 1) � = 1 + � w ( µ ( t )) , µ ( t + 1) − µ ( t ) �

  18. Question: Can you beat the market portfolio ? Given the portfolio map π : int (∆ n ) �→ ∆ n and a sequence ( µ ( t )) m t =1 , we obtain for the relative wealth (in terms of the market portfolio) n � V ( t + 1) µ i ( t + 1) = π i ( µ ( t )) V ( t ) µ i ( t ) i =1 � n = w i ( µ ( t )) µ i ( t + 1) . i =1 = � w ( µ ( t )) , µ ( t + 1) � = 1 + � w ( µ ( t )) , µ ( t + 1) − µ ( t ) �

  19. Question: Can you beat the market portfolio ? Given the portfolio map π : int (∆ n ) �→ ∆ n and a sequence ( µ ( t )) m t =1 , we obtain for the relative wealth (in terms of the market portfolio) n � V ( t + 1) µ i ( t + 1) = π i ( µ ( t )) V ( t ) µ i ( t ) i =1 � n = w i ( µ ( t )) µ i ( t + 1) . i =1 = � w ( µ ( t )) , µ ( t + 1) � = 1 + � w ( µ ( t )) , µ ( t + 1) − µ ( t ) �

  20. Suppose that the market makes a “round trip” µ 1 , µ 2 , . . . , µ m , µ m +1 = µ 1 . Then � m � m V ( m + 1) V ( t + 1) = = [1 + � w ( µ ( t )) , µ ( t + 1) − µ ( t ) � ] (4) V (1) V ( t ) t =1 t =1 is precisely the term appearing in the definition of multiplicative cyclical monotonocity . Taking logarithms yields � m � � � � � m V ( t + 1) log = log 1 + � w ( µ ( t )) , µ ( t + 1) − µ ( t ) � (5) V ( t ) t =1 t =1 Note that w is multiplicatively cyclically monotone iff (4) is always ≥ 1 or, equivalently, (5) is always ≥ 0 .

Recommend


More recommend