Bank Liability Insurance Schemes Before 1865 Warren Weber Conference in Honor of Gary Stern April 23, 2010 Warren Weber Bank Liability Insurance Schemes Before 1865
Introduction Gary known for Too Big To Fail (TBTF) and moral hazard concerns The change in behavior induced by the TBTF guarantee is just one example of so-called moral hazard. Every insurance policy creates a moral hazard, in that the insured have less incentive to monitor risks than they would in the absence of coverage. (Stern-Feldman, p. 17) My focus: moral hazard and risk monitoring . . . but in the context of “deposit insurance” Warren Weber Bank Liability Insurance Schemes Before 1865
Introduction Insurance of bank obligations did not begin with FDIC in 1933 Some state insurance of deposits in the 1920s Federal insurance of all banknotes under the National Banking System starting in 1864 Some state insurance of banknotes (many cases all bank liabilities) prior to the Civil War Warren Weber Bank Liability Insurance Schemes Before 1865
Two basic state insurance schemes 1 Insurance funds (Safety Funds) New York Safety Fund System (1829-1863) Vermont Insurance Fund (1831-1858) 2 Mutual guarantee systems State Bank of Indiana (1834-1863) State Bank of Ohio (1845-1863) Warren Weber Bank Liability Insurance Schemes Before 1865
Introduction According to Henry B. Steagall (1933) the purpose of deposit insurance: Provide public with “money as safe as though it were invested in a 1 government bond” “Prevent bank failures, with depositors walking in the streets” 2 Warren Weber Bank Liability Insurance Schemes Before 1865
Introduction Allan Meltzer in recent Congressional testimony: We cannot have deposit insurance without restricting what banks can do. The right answer is to use regulation to change incentives – making bankers and their shareholders bear the losses. The pre-Civil War experience shows the importance of incentives and who bears losses for controlling moral hazard It also suggests considering schemes with mutualization of losses may be worthwhile Warren Weber Bank Liability Insurance Schemes Before 1865
Outline 1 Brief background on monetary environment 2 Describe basic structure of the two schemes 3 Facts: bank runs, completeness of insurance, bank failures 4 Implications Warren Weber Bank Liability Insurance Schemes Before 1865
Background on the antebellum period Bimetallic commodity money system No central bank Bank regulation state-by-state Banknotes most prevalent medium of exchange Warren Weber Bank Liability Insurance Schemes Before 1865
Warren Weber Bank Liability Insurance Schemes Before 1865
Safety Funds: Basic structure Covered all bank liabilities Banks paid a percentage of capital stock into Fund managed by state Creditors of insolvent banks paid by Fund only after liquidation completed Supervision Warren Weber Bank Liability Insurance Schemes Before 1865
Safety Funds: Basic structure Partial mutualization of losses Additional assessments if Fund reduced by insurance payments Partial because Cap on annual contributions Banks could leave before Fund restored (but only when charter expired) “proportional share” of Fund returned to leaving bank Warren Weber Bank Liability Insurance Schemes Before 1865
Mutual Guarantee: Basic Structure Despite name (State Bank of . . . ), a system of independent banks called Branches Each Branch: had its own stockholders and directors issued own notes redeemable only at that Branch distributed profits only to stockholders of that Branch State Bank did no actual banking Warren Weber Bank Liability Insurance Schemes Before 1865
Mutual Guarantee: Basic Structure State Board overseeing the Branches composed of Some members appointed by legislature 1 member from each Branch Board had power to Close a Branch Limit dividends Limit ratio of loans and discounts to capital Warren Weber Bank Liability Insurance Schemes Before 1865
Mutual Guarantee: Basic Structure Full mutualization of losses: Indiana: Branches mutually guaranteed “all debts, notes, and engagements of each other” Ohio: “Each solvent branch shall contribute . . . to the sum necessary for redeeming the notes of the failing branch” Assessments on survivors and payments to creditors immediate Warren Weber Bank Liability Insurance Schemes Before 1865
Facts: Bank Runs Bank runs under both schemes Although may have made been less lengthy and less likely Warren Weber Bank Liability Insurance Schemes Before 1865
Facts: Completeness of Insurance New York: No losses to creditors, but . . . Failures not fully paid until 5 or 6 years after they occurred In the interim, notes of failed banks discounted between 30% and 50% Vermont: Losses to creditors Indiana and Ohio: No losses to creditors Warren Weber Bank Liability Insurance Schemes Before 1865
Facts: Failure Rates Safety Fund banks’ failure rates generally same or slightly higher than similar uninsured banks State Bank of Ohio: Failure rate about the same as similar banks in state State Bank of Indiana: No failures Warren Weber Bank Liability Insurance Schemes Before 1865
Implications Meltzer’s “right answer” to controlling the moral hazard problem with deposit insurance is to have agents that both have the potential to bear losses 1 can regulate bank behavior 2 The pre-Civil War insurance schemes show these agents do not have to be shareholders or creditors of the bank Warren Weber Bank Liability Insurance Schemes Before 1865
Implications Both Safety Fund and mutual guarantee systems had shareholders of other banks potentially bearing losses However, only the State Bank systems gave other banks the power to regulate Hypothesis: This is why State Bank of Indiana seemed to work better than the Safety Fund systems Warren Weber Bank Liability Insurance Schemes Before 1865
Implications Puzzle: Why didn’t State Bank of Ohio achieve same outcome? Answer: strength of incentives to regulate(“skin in the game”) average liabilities of branches exposure = number of survivors × average capital of branches State Bank of Indiana branches: exposure ≈ 20% State Bank of Ohio branches exposure ≈ 5% Warren Weber Bank Liability Insurance Schemes Before 1865
Implications Another example to illustrate Meltzer’s “right answer”: Suffolk Banking System Par note clearing system in New England, 1825 - 1858 Operated by single bank – the Suffolk Bank in Boston Cleared large value of notes each month Warren Weber Bank Liability Insurance Schemes Before 1865
Implications Assets Liabilities Overdrafts Due to banks Notes of other banks If member bank failed, Suffolk stuck with losses on holdings of that bank’s notes Warren Weber Bank Liability Insurance Schemes Before 1865
Implications Assets Liabilities Overdrafts Due to banks Notes of other banks If member bank failed, Suffolk stuck with losses on holdings of that bank’s notes Warren Weber Bank Liability Insurance Schemes Before 1865
Implications Suffolk Bank did “regulate” member banks It appears evident . . . that too large a portion of your loan is in accommodation paper, which cannot be relied upon at maturity to meet your liabilities.. . . [W]e hope you will take measures to change the character of your loan, and render it more available in case of need. Warren Weber Bank Liability Insurance Schemes Before 1865
Implications New England banks had low failure rates State Number Failures Failure Rate New England States Massachusetts 214 11 5.14 New Hampshire 28 2 7.14 Vermont 52 4 7.69 Maine 60 7 11.67 Other Eastern States New Jersey 86 8 9.30 New York (chartered) 100 14 14.00 Pennsylvania 95 15 15.79 Maryland 44 10 22.73 Warren Weber Bank Liability Insurance Schemes Before 1865
Conclusion Need more thinking about implementing deposit insurance or systemic risk schemes that include a higher degree of mutualization of losses than under present 1 schemes provide survivors with the means to change the incentives of other 2 members of the scheme Warren Weber Bank Liability Insurance Schemes Before 1865
Recommend
More recommend