an introduction to
play

An Introduction to Title Maximum Pawel Zabczyk Likelihood and - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Centre for Central Banking Studies Date Nairobi, April 25, 2016 An Introduction to Title Maximum Pawel Zabczyk Likelihood and pawel.zabczyk@bankofengland.co.uk Optimisation The Bank of England does not accept any liability for misleading


  1. Archie Karas • Started playing Razz, like poker but weakest hand wins • Figured it was great for him given his bad luck • Borrowed $10,000 from old friend... • Repaid loan with 50% interest in 3 hours and had plenty left over to play • Kept on playing for 3 years, and seemed unable to lose • Accumulated $40 million in the process (on many games) • Then came the losses: • $11 million playing craps; in 3 weeks • $17 million trying to get back the 11; in 1 week • $2 million playing poker • Caught cheating at a blackjack table in 2013 (4 years of probation) • Placed in Nevada’s Black Book in 2015 Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 6

  2. Archie Karas • Started playing Razz, like poker but weakest hand wins • Figured it was great for him given his bad luck • Borrowed $10,000 from old friend... • Repaid loan with 50% interest in 3 hours and had plenty left over to play • Kept on playing for 3 years, and seemed unable to lose • Accumulated $40 million in the process (on many games) • Then came the losses: • $11 million playing craps; in 3 weeks • $17 million trying to get back the 11; in 1 week • $2 million playing poker • Caught cheating at a blackjack table in 2013 (4 years of probation) • Placed in Nevada’s Black Book in 2015 Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 6

  3. Archie Karas • Started playing Razz, like poker but weakest hand wins • Figured it was great for him given his bad luck • Borrowed $10,000 from old friend... • Repaid loan with 50% interest in 3 hours and had plenty left over to play • Kept on playing for 3 years, and seemed unable to lose • Accumulated $40 million in the process (on many games) • Then came the losses: • $11 million playing craps; in 3 weeks • $17 million trying to get back the 11; in 1 week • $2 million playing poker • Caught cheating at a blackjack table in 2013 (4 years of probation) • Placed in Nevada’s Black Book in 2015 Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 6

  4. Archie Karas • Started playing Razz, like poker but weakest hand wins • Figured it was great for him given his bad luck • Borrowed $10,000 from old friend... • Repaid loan with 50% interest in 3 hours and had plenty left over to play • Kept on playing for 3 years, and seemed unable to lose • Accumulated $40 million in the process (on many games) • Then came the losses: • $11 million playing craps; in 3 weeks • $17 million trying to get back the 11; in 1 week • $2 million playing poker • Caught cheating at a blackjack table in 2013 (4 years of probation) • Placed in Nevada’s Black Book in 2015 Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 6

  5. Archie Karas • Started playing Razz, like poker but weakest hand wins • Figured it was great for him given his bad luck • Borrowed $10,000 from old friend... • Repaid loan with 50% interest in 3 hours and had plenty left over to play • Kept on playing for 3 years, and seemed unable to lose • Accumulated $40 million in the process (on many games) • Then came the losses: • $11 million playing craps; in 3 weeks • $17 million trying to get back the 11; in 1 week • $2 million playing poker • Caught cheating at a blackjack table in 2013 (4 years of probation) • Placed in Nevada’s Black Book in 2015 Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 6

  6. Archie Karas • Started playing Razz, like poker but weakest hand wins • Figured it was great for him given his bad luck • Borrowed $10,000 from old friend... • Repaid loan with 50% interest in 3 hours and had plenty left over to play • Kept on playing for 3 years, and seemed unable to lose • Accumulated $40 million in the process (on many games) • Then came the losses: • $11 million playing craps; in 3 weeks • $17 million trying to get back the 11; in 1 week • $2 million playing poker • Caught cheating at a blackjack table in 2013 (4 years of probation) • Placed in Nevada’s Black Book in 2015 Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 6

  7. Archie Karas • Started playing Razz, like poker but weakest hand wins • Figured it was great for him given his bad luck • Borrowed $10,000 from old friend... • Repaid loan with 50% interest in 3 hours and had plenty left over to play • Kept on playing for 3 years, and seemed unable to lose • Accumulated $40 million in the process (on many games) • Then came the losses: • $11 million playing craps; in 3 weeks • $17 million trying to get back the 11; in 1 week • $2 million playing poker • Caught cheating at a blackjack table in 2013 (4 years of probation) • Placed in Nevada’s Black Book in 2015 Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 6

  8. Archie Karas • Started playing Razz, like poker but weakest hand wins • Figured it was great for him given his bad luck • Borrowed $10,000 from old friend... • Repaid loan with 50% interest in 3 hours and had plenty left over to play • Kept on playing for 3 years, and seemed unable to lose • Accumulated $40 million in the process (on many games) • Then came the losses: • $11 million playing craps; in 3 weeks • $17 million trying to get back the 11; in 1 week • $2 million playing poker • Caught cheating at a blackjack table in 2013 (4 years of probation) • Placed in Nevada’s Black Book in 2015 Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 6

  9. Archie Karas • Started playing Razz, like poker but weakest hand wins • Figured it was great for him given his bad luck • Borrowed $10,000 from old friend... • Repaid loan with 50% interest in 3 hours and had plenty left over to play • Kept on playing for 3 years, and seemed unable to lose • Accumulated $40 million in the process (on many games) • Then came the losses: • $11 million playing craps; in 3 weeks • $17 million trying to get back the 11; in 1 week • $2 million playing poker • Caught cheating at a blackjack table in 2013 (4 years of probation) • Placed in Nevada’s Black Book in 2015 Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 6

  10. Archie Karas • Started playing Razz, like poker but weakest hand wins • Figured it was great for him given his bad luck • Borrowed $10,000 from old friend... • Repaid loan with 50% interest in 3 hours and had plenty left over to play • Kept on playing for 3 years, and seemed unable to lose • Accumulated $40 million in the process (on many games) • Then came the losses: • $11 million playing craps; in 3 weeks • $17 million trying to get back the 11; in 1 week • $2 million playing poker • Caught cheating at a blackjack table in 2013 (4 years of probation) • Placed in Nevada’s Black Book in 2015 Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 6

  11. Archie Karas • Started playing Razz, like poker but weakest hand wins • Figured it was great for him given his bad luck • Borrowed $10,000 from old friend... • Repaid loan with 50% interest in 3 hours and had plenty left over to play • Kept on playing for 3 years, and seemed unable to lose • Accumulated $40 million in the process (on many games) • Then came the losses: • $11 million playing craps; in 3 weeks • $17 million trying to get back the 11; in 1 week • $2 million playing poker • Caught cheating at a blackjack table in 2013 (4 years of probation) • Placed in Nevada’s Black Book in 2015 Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 6

  12. Thought experiment • Imagine you are head of security in a casino (pre-2015) • Archie comes through the door... • He wants to play high-stakes coin toss • Every game costs $1 million • Heads: he wins $2 million (stake + $1 million extra) • Tails: he loses his $1 million stake • Archie insists on using his own ‘lucky’ coin • You have limited time and can inspect the coin • How do you decide whether to allow him to play or not? Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 7

  13. Thought experiment • Imagine you are head of security in a casino (pre-2015) • Archie comes through the door... • He wants to play high-stakes coin toss • Every game costs $1 million • Heads: he wins $2 million (stake + $1 million extra) • Tails: he loses his $1 million stake • Archie insists on using his own ‘lucky’ coin • You have limited time and can inspect the coin • How do you decide whether to allow him to play or not? Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 7

  14. Thought experiment • Imagine you are head of security in a casino (pre-2015) • Archie comes through the door... • He wants to play high-stakes coin toss • Every game costs $1 million • Heads: he wins $2 million (stake + $1 million extra) • Tails: he loses his $1 million stake • Archie insists on using his own ‘lucky’ coin • You have limited time and can inspect the coin • How do you decide whether to allow him to play or not? Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 7

  15. Thought experiment • Imagine you are head of security in a casino (pre-2015) • Archie comes through the door... • He wants to play high-stakes coin toss • Every game costs $1 million • Heads: he wins $2 million (stake + $1 million extra) • Tails: he loses his $1 million stake • Archie insists on using his own ‘lucky’ coin • You have limited time and can inspect the coin • How do you decide whether to allow him to play or not? Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 7

  16. Thought experiment • Imagine you are head of security in a casino (pre-2015) • Archie comes through the door... • He wants to play high-stakes coin toss • Every game costs $1 million • Heads: he wins $2 million (stake + $1 million extra) • Tails: he loses his $1 million stake • Archie insists on using his own ‘lucky’ coin • You have limited time and can inspect the coin • How do you decide whether to allow him to play or not? Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 7

  17. Thought experiment • Imagine you are head of security in a casino (pre-2015) • Archie comes through the door... • He wants to play high-stakes coin toss • Every game costs $1 million • Heads: he wins $2 million (stake + $1 million extra) • Tails: he loses his $1 million stake • Archie insists on using his own ‘lucky’ coin • You have limited time and can inspect the coin • How do you decide whether to allow him to play or not? Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 7

  18. Thought experiment • Imagine you are head of security in a casino (pre-2015) • Archie comes through the door... • He wants to play high-stakes coin toss • Every game costs $1 million • Heads: he wins $2 million (stake + $1 million extra) • Tails: he loses his $1 million stake • Archie insists on using his own ‘lucky’ coin • You have limited time and can inspect the coin • How do you decide whether to allow him to play or not? Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 7

  19. Thought experiment • Imagine you are head of security in a casino (pre-2015) • Archie comes through the door... • He wants to play high-stakes coin toss • Every game costs $1 million • Heads: he wins $2 million (stake + $1 million extra) • Tails: he loses his $1 million stake • Archie insists on using his own ‘lucky’ coin • You have limited time and can inspect the coin • How do you decide whether to allow him to play or not? Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 7

  20. Thought experiment • Imagine you are head of security in a casino (pre-2015) • Archie comes through the door... • He wants to play high-stakes coin toss • Every game costs $1 million • Heads: he wins $2 million (stake + $1 million extra) • Tails: he loses his $1 million stake • Archie insists on using his own ‘lucky’ coin • You have limited time and can inspect the coin • How do you decide whether to allow him to play or not? Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 7

  21. A primer on maximum likelihood • We really care about the probability of ending up with heads: q ∗ • The probability q ∗ is unknown - Archie may have done something to the coin • Maximum likelihood provides a way of estimating q ∗ Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 8

  22. A primer on maximum likelihood • We really care about the probability of ending up with heads: q ∗ • The probability q ∗ is unknown - Archie may have done something to the coin • Maximum likelihood provides a way of estimating q ∗ Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 8

  23. A primer on maximum likelihood • We really care about the probability of ending up with heads: q ∗ • The probability q ∗ is unknown - Archie may have done something to the coin • Maximum likelihood provides a way of estimating q ∗ Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 8

  24. Idea • Generate data x by tossing the coin and noting results • We then form a likelihood function L ( q | x ) n � L ( q | x ) ≡ p ( x | q ) = p ( x i | q ) i = 1 • Here • q is number between 0 and 1 • p ( x | q ) denotes the probability of observing x if the probability of heads equals q • p ( x i | q ) is the probabilityof observing x i in throw i conditional on q • A maximum likelihood (ML) estimator of the unknown parameter q ∗ is the argument ˆ q which maximises the likelihood function L ( ·| x ) • Of course ˆ q is conditional on the entire sample x ! Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 9

  25. Idea • Generate data x by tossing the coin and noting results • We then form a likelihood function L ( q | x ) n � L ( q | x ) ≡ p ( x | q ) = p ( x i | q ) i = 1 • Here • q is number between 0 and 1 • p ( x | q ) denotes the probability of observing x if the probability of heads equals q • p ( x i | q ) is the probabilityof observing x i in throw i conditional on q • A maximum likelihood (ML) estimator of the unknown parameter q ∗ is the argument ˆ q which maximises the likelihood function L ( ·| x ) • Of course ˆ q is conditional on the entire sample x ! Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 9

  26. Idea • Generate data x by tossing the coin and noting results • We then form a likelihood function L ( q | x ) n � L ( q | x ) ≡ p ( x | q ) = p ( x i | q ) i = 1 • Here • q is number between 0 and 1 • p ( x | q ) denotes the probability of observing x if the probability of heads equals q • p ( x i | q ) is the probabilityof observing x i in throw i conditional on q • A maximum likelihood (ML) estimator of the unknown parameter q ∗ is the argument ˆ q which maximises the likelihood function L ( ·| x ) • Of course ˆ q is conditional on the entire sample x ! Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 9

  27. Idea • Generate data x by tossing the coin and noting results • We then form a likelihood function L ( q | x ) n � L ( q | x ) ≡ p ( x | q ) = p ( x i | q ) i = 1 • Here • q is number between 0 and 1 • p ( x | q ) denotes the probability of observing x if the probability of heads equals q • p ( x i | q ) is the probabilityof observing x i in throw i conditional on q • A maximum likelihood (ML) estimator of the unknown parameter q ∗ is the argument ˆ q which maximises the likelihood function L ( ·| x ) • Of course ˆ q is conditional on the entire sample x ! Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 9

  28. Idea • Generate data x by tossing the coin and noting results • We then form a likelihood function L ( q | x ) n � L ( q | x ) ≡ p ( x | q ) = p ( x i | q ) i = 1 • Here • q is number between 0 and 1 • p ( x | q ) denotes the probability of observing x if the probability of heads equals q • p ( x i | q ) is the probabilityof observing x i in throw i conditional on q • A maximum likelihood (ML) estimator of the unknown parameter q ∗ is the argument ˆ q which maximises the likelihood function L ( ·| x ) • Of course ˆ q is conditional on the entire sample x ! Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 9

  29. Idea • Generate data x by tossing the coin and noting results • We then form a likelihood function L ( q | x ) n � L ( q | x ) ≡ p ( x | q ) = p ( x i | q ) i = 1 • Here • q is number between 0 and 1 • p ( x | q ) denotes the probability of observing x if the probability of heads equals q • p ( x i | q ) is the probabilityof observing x i in throw i conditional on q • A maximum likelihood (ML) estimator of the unknown parameter q ∗ is the argument ˆ q which maximises the likelihood function L ( ·| x ) • Of course ˆ q is conditional on the entire sample x ! Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 9

  30. Idea • Generate data x by tossing the coin and noting results • We then form a likelihood function L ( q | x ) n � L ( q | x ) ≡ p ( x | q ) = p ( x i | q ) i = 1 • Here • q is number between 0 and 1 • p ( x | q ) denotes the probability of observing x if the probability of heads equals q • p ( x i | q ) is the probabilityof observing x i in throw i conditional on q • A maximum likelihood (ML) estimator of the unknown parameter q ∗ is the argument ˆ q which maximises the likelihood function L ( ·| x ) • Of course ˆ q is conditional on the entire sample x ! Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 9

  31. Idea • Generate data x by tossing the coin and noting results • We then form a likelihood function L ( q | x ) n � L ( q | x ) ≡ p ( x | q ) = p ( x i | q ) i = 1 • Here • q is number between 0 and 1 • p ( x | q ) denotes the probability of observing x if the probability of heads equals q • p ( x i | q ) is the probabilityof observing x i in throw i conditional on q • A maximum likelihood (ML) estimator of the unknown parameter q ∗ is the argument ˆ q which maximises the likelihood function L ( ·| x ) • Of course ˆ q is conditional on the entire sample x ! Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 9

  32. Binomial example • What is the probability of observing tails ( T ) if the probability of heads ( H ) is p ( H ) = q ∗ ? • Single unknown parameter q ∗ to be estimated • Assume we observed a sequence: HTHH . . . TT • What is the corresponding probability as a function of q ∗ ? p ( H | q ∗ ) · p ( T | q ∗ ) · p ( H | q ∗ ) · p ( H | q ∗ ) . . . p ( T | q ∗ ) · p ( T | q ∗ ) Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 10

  33. Binomial example • What is the probability of observing tails ( T ) if the probability of heads ( H ) is p ( H ) = q ∗ ? • Single unknown parameter q ∗ to be estimated • Assume we observed a sequence: HTHH . . . TT • What is the corresponding probability as a function of q ∗ ? p ( H | q ∗ ) · p ( T | q ∗ ) · p ( H | q ∗ ) · p ( H | q ∗ ) . . . p ( T | q ∗ ) · p ( T | q ∗ ) Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 10

  34. Binomial example • What is the probability of observing tails ( T ) if the probability of heads ( H ) is p ( H ) = q ∗ ? • Single unknown parameter q ∗ to be estimated • Assume we observed a sequence: HTHH . . . TT • What is the corresponding probability as a function of q ∗ ? p ( H | q ∗ ) · p ( T | q ∗ ) · p ( H | q ∗ ) · p ( H | q ∗ ) . . . p ( T | q ∗ ) · p ( T | q ∗ ) Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 10

  35. Binomial example • What is the probability of observing tails ( T ) if the probability of heads ( H ) is p ( H ) = q ∗ ? • Single unknown parameter q ∗ to be estimated • Assume we observed a sequence: HTHH . . . TT • What is the corresponding probability as a function of q ∗ ? p ( H | q ∗ ) · p ( T | q ∗ ) · p ( H | q ∗ ) · p ( H | q ∗ ) . . . p ( T | q ∗ ) · p ( T | q ∗ ) Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 10

  36. Binomial example (ctd.) • To estimate q ∗ define the likelihood L ( q | HTHH . . . TT ) = p ( H | q ) · p ( T | q ) · p ( H | q ) · p ( H | q ) . . . . . . p ( T | q ) · p ( T | q ) = q k ( 1 − q ) n − k • What are k and n ? • The ML estimator of the unknown parameter q ∗ is the ˆ q which maximises the likelihood function L ( q | HTHH . . . TT ) Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 11

  37. Binomial example (ctd.) • To estimate q ∗ define the likelihood L ( q | HTHH . . . TT ) = p ( H | q ) · p ( T | q ) · p ( H | q ) · p ( H | q ) . . . . . . p ( T | q ) · p ( T | q ) = q k ( 1 − q ) n − k • What are k and n ? • The ML estimator of the unknown parameter q ∗ is the ˆ q which maximises the likelihood function L ( q | HTHH . . . TT ) Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 11

  38. Binomial example (ctd.) • To estimate q ∗ define the likelihood L ( q | HTHH . . . TT ) = p ( H | q ) · p ( T | q ) · p ( H | q ) · p ( H | q ) . . . . . . p ( T | q ) · p ( T | q ) = q k ( 1 − q ) n − k • What are k and n ? • The ML estimator of the unknown parameter q ∗ is the ˆ q which maximises the likelihood function L ( q | HTHH . . . TT ) Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 11

  39. Binomial example (ctd.) • Exercise 1. Find the ML estimator of q ∗ conditional on observing the sequence H , H , H , T , T , H , T , H , T , H • What is the likelihood function L ( q | H , H , H , T , T , H , T , H , T , H ) ? • We can plot this function to see if it has a maximum • Important to understand what this function shows us! Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 12

  40. Binomial example (ctd.) • Exercise 1. Find the ML estimator of q ∗ conditional on observing the sequence H , H , H , T , T , H , T , H , T , H • What is the likelihood function L ( q | H , H , H , T , T , H , T , H , T , H ) ? • We can plot this function to see if it has a maximum • Important to understand what this function shows us! Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 12

  41. Binomial example (ctd.) • Exercise 1. Find the ML estimator of q ∗ conditional on observing the sequence H , H , H , T , T , H , T , H , T , H • What is the likelihood function L ( q | H , H , H , T , T , H , T , H , T , H ) ? • We can plot this function to see if it has a maximum • Important to understand what this function shows us! Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 12

  42. Binomial example (ctd.) • Exercise 1. Find the ML estimator of q ∗ conditional on observing the sequence H , H , H , T , T , H , T , H , T , H • What is the likelihood function L ( q | H , H , H , T , T , H , T , H , T , H ) ? • We can plot this function to see if it has a maximum • Important to understand what this function shows us! Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 12

  43. Binomial example (ctd.) −3 1.2 x 10 1 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0 0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1 Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 13

  44. Binomial example (ctd.) • We could solve for the maximum analytically • To do so take the derivative of the likelihood function L ( q | H , H , H , T , T , H , T , H , T , H ) ≡ q 6 ( 1 − q ) 4 with respect to q and set it equal to zero ∂ L ( q | H , H , H , T , T , H , T , H , T , H ) ≡ 6 q 5 ( 1 − q ) 4 − 4 q 6 ( 1 − q ) 3 ∂ q = q 5 ( 1 − q ) 3 ( 6 ( 1 − q ) − 4 q ) ≡ 0 • Eliminating 0 and 1 as maximum candidates (why?) = ⇒ 6 ( 1 − ˆ q ) − 4 ˆ q = 0 ⇔ 10 ˆ q = 6 ⇔ ˆ q = 0 . 6 • ML estimator of q ∗ is 0.6! • Note that this does not account for any prior beliefs we may have had about Archie being dishonest Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 14

  45. Binomial example (ctd.) • We could solve for the maximum analytically • To do so take the derivative of the likelihood function L ( q | H , H , H , T , T , H , T , H , T , H ) ≡ q 6 ( 1 − q ) 4 with respect to q and set it equal to zero ∂ L ( q | H , H , H , T , T , H , T , H , T , H ) ≡ 6 q 5 ( 1 − q ) 4 − 4 q 6 ( 1 − q ) 3 ∂ q = q 5 ( 1 − q ) 3 ( 6 ( 1 − q ) − 4 q ) ≡ 0 • Eliminating 0 and 1 as maximum candidates (why?) = ⇒ 6 ( 1 − ˆ q ) − 4 ˆ q = 0 ⇔ 10 ˆ q = 6 ⇔ ˆ q = 0 . 6 • ML estimator of q ∗ is 0.6! • Note that this does not account for any prior beliefs we may have had about Archie being dishonest Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 14

  46. Binomial example (ctd.) • We could solve for the maximum analytically • To do so take the derivative of the likelihood function L ( q | H , H , H , T , T , H , T , H , T , H ) ≡ q 6 ( 1 − q ) 4 with respect to q and set it equal to zero ∂ L ( q | H , H , H , T , T , H , T , H , T , H ) ≡ 6 q 5 ( 1 − q ) 4 − 4 q 6 ( 1 − q ) 3 ∂ q = q 5 ( 1 − q ) 3 ( 6 ( 1 − q ) − 4 q ) ≡ 0 • Eliminating 0 and 1 as maximum candidates (why?) = ⇒ 6 ( 1 − ˆ q ) − 4 ˆ q = 0 ⇔ 10 ˆ q = 6 ⇔ ˆ q = 0 . 6 • ML estimator of q ∗ is 0.6! • Note that this does not account for any prior beliefs we may have had about Archie being dishonest Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 14

  47. Binomial example (ctd.) • We could solve for the maximum analytically • To do so take the derivative of the likelihood function L ( q | H , H , H , T , T , H , T , H , T , H ) ≡ q 6 ( 1 − q ) 4 with respect to q and set it equal to zero ∂ L ( q | H , H , H , T , T , H , T , H , T , H ) ≡ 6 q 5 ( 1 − q ) 4 − 4 q 6 ( 1 − q ) 3 ∂ q = q 5 ( 1 − q ) 3 ( 6 ( 1 − q ) − 4 q ) ≡ 0 • Eliminating 0 and 1 as maximum candidates (why?) = ⇒ 6 ( 1 − ˆ q ) − 4 ˆ q = 0 ⇔ 10 ˆ q = 6 ⇔ ˆ q = 0 . 6 • ML estimator of q ∗ is 0.6! • Note that this does not account for any prior beliefs we may have had about Archie being dishonest Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 14

  48. Binomial example (ctd.) • We could solve for the maximum analytically • To do so take the derivative of the likelihood function L ( q | H , H , H , T , T , H , T , H , T , H ) ≡ q 6 ( 1 − q ) 4 with respect to q and set it equal to zero ∂ L ( q | H , H , H , T , T , H , T , H , T , H ) ≡ 6 q 5 ( 1 − q ) 4 − 4 q 6 ( 1 − q ) 3 ∂ q = q 5 ( 1 − q ) 3 ( 6 ( 1 − q ) − 4 q ) ≡ 0 • Eliminating 0 and 1 as maximum candidates (why?) = ⇒ 6 ( 1 − ˆ q ) − 4 ˆ q = 0 ⇔ 10 ˆ q = 6 ⇔ ˆ q = 0 . 6 • ML estimator of q ∗ is 0.6! • Note that this does not account for any prior beliefs we may have had about Archie being dishonest Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 14

  49. Univariate regression • Now, consider a univariate regression model, where B ∗ and σ ∗ are to be estimated y t = B ∗ x t + v t , v t ∼ N . i . d . ( 0 , ( σ ∗ ) 2 ) Independence and the assumption of normality imply � � 1 1 2 ( σ ∗ ) 2 v 2 p ( v t ) = √ 2 πσ ∗ exp − t • What is the likelihood function L ( B , σ 2 | x 1 , x 2 , . . . , x n , y 1 , y 2 , . . . , y n ) ? • Idea: estimate B ∗ and σ ∗ by finding the maximum of the likelihood function with respect to B and σ • Just like the coin toss example except now we have two parameters! • In what follows x ≡ ( x 1 , x 2 , . . . , x n ) , y ≡ ( y 1 , y 2 , . . . , y n ) Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 15

  50. Univariate regression • Now, consider a univariate regression model, where B ∗ and σ ∗ are to be estimated y t = B ∗ x t + v t , v t ∼ N . i . d . ( 0 , ( σ ∗ ) 2 ) Independence and the assumption of normality imply � � 1 1 2 ( σ ∗ ) 2 v 2 p ( v t ) = √ 2 πσ ∗ exp − t • What is the likelihood function L ( B , σ 2 | x 1 , x 2 , . . . , x n , y 1 , y 2 , . . . , y n ) ? • Idea: estimate B ∗ and σ ∗ by finding the maximum of the likelihood function with respect to B and σ • Just like the coin toss example except now we have two parameters! • In what follows x ≡ ( x 1 , x 2 , . . . , x n ) , y ≡ ( y 1 , y 2 , . . . , y n ) Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 15

  51. Univariate regression • Now, consider a univariate regression model, where B ∗ and σ ∗ are to be estimated y t = B ∗ x t + v t , v t ∼ N . i . d . ( 0 , ( σ ∗ ) 2 ) Independence and the assumption of normality imply � � 1 1 2 ( σ ∗ ) 2 v 2 p ( v t ) = √ 2 πσ ∗ exp − t • What is the likelihood function L ( B , σ 2 | x 1 , x 2 , . . . , x n , y 1 , y 2 , . . . , y n ) ? • Idea: estimate B ∗ and σ ∗ by finding the maximum of the likelihood function with respect to B and σ • Just like the coin toss example except now we have two parameters! • In what follows x ≡ ( x 1 , x 2 , . . . , x n ) , y ≡ ( y 1 , y 2 , . . . , y n ) Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 15

  52. Univariate regression • Now, consider a univariate regression model, where B ∗ and σ ∗ are to be estimated y t = B ∗ x t + v t , v t ∼ N . i . d . ( 0 , ( σ ∗ ) 2 ) Independence and the assumption of normality imply � � 1 1 2 ( σ ∗ ) 2 v 2 p ( v t ) = √ 2 πσ ∗ exp − t • What is the likelihood function L ( B , σ 2 | x 1 , x 2 , . . . , x n , y 1 , y 2 , . . . , y n ) ? • Idea: estimate B ∗ and σ ∗ by finding the maximum of the likelihood function with respect to B and σ • Just like the coin toss example except now we have two parameters! • In what follows x ≡ ( x 1 , x 2 , . . . , x n ) , y ≡ ( y 1 , y 2 , . . . , y n ) Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 15

  53. Univariate regression • Now, consider a univariate regression model, where B ∗ and σ ∗ are to be estimated y t = B ∗ x t + v t , v t ∼ N . i . d . ( 0 , ( σ ∗ ) 2 ) Independence and the assumption of normality imply � � 1 1 2 ( σ ∗ ) 2 v 2 p ( v t ) = √ 2 πσ ∗ exp − t • What is the likelihood function L ( B , σ 2 | x 1 , x 2 , . . . , x n , y 1 , y 2 , . . . , y n ) ? • Idea: estimate B ∗ and σ ∗ by finding the maximum of the likelihood function with respect to B and σ • Just like the coin toss example except now we have two parameters! • In what follows x ≡ ( x 1 , x 2 , . . . , x n ) , y ≡ ( y 1 , y 2 , . . . , y n ) Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 15

  54. ML estimates of population parameters (ctd.) • Turns out to be easier to differentiate the log of the likelihood rather than the likelihood itself • This is equivalent, since L ( B , σ 2 | x , y ) > 0 and because � � ∂ 1 ∂ L ( B , σ 2 | x , y ) ∂ B L ( B , σ 2 | x , y ) ∂ B ln = L ( B , σ 2 | x , y ) • How does this help us? • We then have � ( y i − Bx i ) 2 � � � n � = − n 2 ln ( 2 π ) − n 2 ln σ 2 − 1 L ( B , σ 2 | x , y ) ln σ 2 2 i = 1 Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 16

  55. ML estimates of population parameters (ctd.) • Turns out to be easier to differentiate the log of the likelihood rather than the likelihood itself • This is equivalent, since L ( B , σ 2 | x , y ) > 0 and because � � ∂ 1 ∂ L ( B , σ 2 | x , y ) ∂ B L ( B , σ 2 | x , y ) ∂ B ln = L ( B , σ 2 | x , y ) • How does this help us? • We then have � ( y i − Bx i ) 2 � � � n � = − n 2 ln ( 2 π ) − n 2 ln σ 2 − 1 L ( B , σ 2 | x , y ) ln σ 2 2 i = 1 Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 16

  56. ML estimates of population parameters (ctd.) • Turns out to be easier to differentiate the log of the likelihood rather than the likelihood itself • This is equivalent, since L ( B , σ 2 | x , y ) > 0 and because � � ∂ 1 ∂ L ( B , σ 2 | x , y ) ∂ B L ( B , σ 2 | x , y ) ∂ B ln = L ( B , σ 2 | x , y ) • How does this help us? • We then have � ( y i − Bx i ) 2 � � � n � = − n 2 ln ( 2 π ) − n 2 ln σ 2 − 1 L ( B , σ 2 | x , y ) ln σ 2 2 i = 1 Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 16

  57. ML estimates of population parameters (ctd.) • Turns out to be easier to differentiate the log of the likelihood rather than the likelihood itself • This is equivalent, since L ( B , σ 2 | x , y ) > 0 and because � � ∂ 1 ∂ L ( B , σ 2 | x , y ) ∂ B L ( B , σ 2 | x , y ) ∂ B ln = L ( B , σ 2 | x , y ) • How does this help us? • We then have � ( y i − Bx i ) 2 � � � n � = − n 2 ln ( 2 π ) − n 2 ln σ 2 − 1 L ( B , σ 2 | x , y ) ln σ 2 2 i = 1 Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 16

  58. ML estimates of population parameters (ctd.) • The first order conditions, or the likelihood equations are � � � � n L ( B , σ 2 | x , y ) � ∂ ln = 1 � ( y i − ˆ Bx i ) x i = 0 � σ 2 ∂ B � ˆ (ˆ i = 1 B , ˆ σ ) � � � � n � L ( B , σ 2 | x , y ) ∂ ln = − n 1 � Bx i ) 2 = 0 ( y i − ˆ � σ 2 + ∂σ 2 σ 4 � 2 ˆ 2 ˆ (ˆ i = 1 B , ˆ σ ) Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 17

  59. ML estimates of population parameters (ctd.) • From the first of these � n � − 1 � � n n � � � � � − 1 � � y i x i − ˆ = 0 ⇒ ˆ x ′ x x ′ y Bx i x i B = x i x i x i y i = i = 1 i = 1 i = 1 • The maximum likelihood estimate of B ∗ is therefore ˆ B given by the familiar formula above • From the second we obtain � � ′ � � y − ˆ y − ˆ n n B x B x � � − n + 1 σ 2 = 1 Bx i ) 2 = 0 ⇒ ˆ Bx i ) 2 = ( y i − ˆ ( y i − ˆ σ 2 n n ˆ i = 1 i = 1 • ML estimate of σ 2 divided through by n (not n − k ) so biased in small samples but not asymptotically • This is quite typical of ML estimates Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 18

  60. ML estimates of population parameters (ctd.) • From the first of these � n � − 1 � � n n � � � � � − 1 � � y i x i − ˆ = 0 ⇒ ˆ x ′ x x ′ y Bx i x i B = x i x i x i y i = i = 1 i = 1 i = 1 • The maximum likelihood estimate of B ∗ is therefore ˆ B given by the familiar formula above • From the second we obtain � � ′ � � y − ˆ y − ˆ n n B x B x � � − n + 1 σ 2 = 1 Bx i ) 2 = 0 ⇒ ˆ Bx i ) 2 = ( y i − ˆ ( y i − ˆ σ 2 n n ˆ i = 1 i = 1 • ML estimate of σ 2 divided through by n (not n − k ) so biased in small samples but not asymptotically • This is quite typical of ML estimates Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 18

  61. ML estimates of population parameters (ctd.) • From the first of these � n � − 1 � � n n � � � � � − 1 � � y i x i − ˆ = 0 ⇒ ˆ x ′ x x ′ y Bx i x i B = x i x i x i y i = i = 1 i = 1 i = 1 • The maximum likelihood estimate of B ∗ is therefore ˆ B given by the familiar formula above • From the second we obtain � � ′ � � y − ˆ y − ˆ n n B x B x � � − n + 1 σ 2 = 1 Bx i ) 2 = 0 ⇒ ˆ Bx i ) 2 = ( y i − ˆ ( y i − ˆ σ 2 n n ˆ i = 1 i = 1 • ML estimate of σ 2 divided through by n (not n − k ) so biased in small samples but not asymptotically • This is quite typical of ML estimates Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 18

  62. ML estimates of population parameters (ctd.) • From the first of these � n � − 1 � � n n � � � � � − 1 � � y i x i − ˆ = 0 ⇒ ˆ x ′ x x ′ y Bx i x i B = x i x i x i y i = i = 1 i = 1 i = 1 • The maximum likelihood estimate of B ∗ is therefore ˆ B given by the familiar formula above • From the second we obtain � � ′ � � y − ˆ y − ˆ n n B x B x � � − n + 1 σ 2 = 1 Bx i ) 2 = 0 ⇒ ˆ Bx i ) 2 = ( y i − ˆ ( y i − ˆ σ 2 n n ˆ i = 1 i = 1 • ML estimate of σ 2 divided through by n (not n − k ) so biased in small samples but not asymptotically • This is quite typical of ML estimates Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 18

  63. ML estimates of population parameters (ctd.) • From the first of these � n � − 1 � � n n � � � � � − 1 � � y i x i − ˆ = 0 ⇒ ˆ x ′ x x ′ y Bx i x i B = x i x i x i y i = i = 1 i = 1 i = 1 • The maximum likelihood estimate of B ∗ is therefore ˆ B given by the familiar formula above • From the second we obtain � � ′ � � y − ˆ y − ˆ n n B x B x � � − n + 1 σ 2 = 1 Bx i ) 2 = 0 ⇒ ˆ Bx i ) 2 = ( y i − ˆ ( y i − ˆ σ 2 n n ˆ i = 1 i = 1 • ML estimate of σ 2 divided through by n (not n − k ) so biased in small samples but not asymptotically • This is quite typical of ML estimates Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 18

  64. Summary of ML approach to linear regression • We wanted to estimate B ∗ and σ ∗ in the following model v t ∼ N ( 0 , ( σ ∗ ) 2 ) y t = B ∗ x t + v t , • To do that, we wrote down the likelihood function � � � 2 πσ 2 � − n / 2 − ( y − B x ) ′ ( y − B x ) L ( B , σ 2 | x , y ) = exp 2 σ 2 • Plugging in data and maximising L ( B , σ 2 | x , y ) with respect to B and σ 2 gave us the standard OLS estimator � � ′ � � B = ( x ′ x ) − 1 ( x ′ y ) and ˆ σ 2 = ˆ y − ˆ y − ˆ B x B x / n • The procedure only incorporated information in x and y ! • The Bayesian approach will allow us to combine prior beliefs about B ∗ and σ ∗ with information in x and y Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 19

  65. Summary of ML approach to linear regression • We wanted to estimate B ∗ and σ ∗ in the following model v t ∼ N ( 0 , ( σ ∗ ) 2 ) y t = B ∗ x t + v t , • To do that, we wrote down the likelihood function � � � 2 πσ 2 � − n / 2 − ( y − B x ) ′ ( y − B x ) L ( B , σ 2 | x , y ) = exp 2 σ 2 • Plugging in data and maximising L ( B , σ 2 | x , y ) with respect to B and σ 2 gave us the standard OLS estimator � � ′ � � B = ( x ′ x ) − 1 ( x ′ y ) and ˆ σ 2 = ˆ y − ˆ y − ˆ B x B x / n • The procedure only incorporated information in x and y ! • The Bayesian approach will allow us to combine prior beliefs about B ∗ and σ ∗ with information in x and y Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 19

  66. Summary of ML approach to linear regression • We wanted to estimate B ∗ and σ ∗ in the following model v t ∼ N ( 0 , ( σ ∗ ) 2 ) y t = B ∗ x t + v t , • To do that, we wrote down the likelihood function � � � 2 πσ 2 � − n / 2 − ( y − B x ) ′ ( y − B x ) L ( B , σ 2 | x , y ) = exp 2 σ 2 • Plugging in data and maximising L ( B , σ 2 | x , y ) with respect to B and σ 2 gave us the standard OLS estimator � � ′ � � B = ( x ′ x ) − 1 ( x ′ y ) and ˆ σ 2 = ˆ y − ˆ y − ˆ B x B x / n • The procedure only incorporated information in x and y ! • The Bayesian approach will allow us to combine prior beliefs about B ∗ and σ ∗ with information in x and y Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 19

  67. Summary of ML approach to linear regression • We wanted to estimate B ∗ and σ ∗ in the following model v t ∼ N ( 0 , ( σ ∗ ) 2 ) y t = B ∗ x t + v t , • To do that, we wrote down the likelihood function � � � 2 πσ 2 � − n / 2 − ( y − B x ) ′ ( y − B x ) L ( B , σ 2 | x , y ) = exp 2 σ 2 • Plugging in data and maximising L ( B , σ 2 | x , y ) with respect to B and σ 2 gave us the standard OLS estimator � � ′ � � B = ( x ′ x ) − 1 ( x ′ y ) and ˆ σ 2 = ˆ y − ˆ y − ˆ B x B x / n • The procedure only incorporated information in x and y ! • The Bayesian approach will allow us to combine prior beliefs about B ∗ and σ ∗ with information in x and y Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 19

  68. Summary of ML approach to linear regression • We wanted to estimate B ∗ and σ ∗ in the following model v t ∼ N ( 0 , ( σ ∗ ) 2 ) y t = B ∗ x t + v t , • To do that, we wrote down the likelihood function � � � 2 πσ 2 � − n / 2 − ( y − B x ) ′ ( y − B x ) L ( B , σ 2 | x , y ) = exp 2 σ 2 • Plugging in data and maximising L ( B , σ 2 | x , y ) with respect to B and σ 2 gave us the standard OLS estimator � � ′ � � B = ( x ′ x ) − 1 ( x ′ y ) and ˆ σ 2 = ˆ y − ˆ y − ˆ B x B x / n • The procedure only incorporated information in x and y ! • The Bayesian approach will allow us to combine prior beliefs about B ∗ and σ ∗ with information in x and y Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 19

  69. ML score and information • At the optimum there are two matrices we will use later in testing • The efficient score matrix is ∂ ln L ( θ ) = S ( θ ) ∂θ • This should be zero at ML estimate • The information matrix is given by � � − ∂ ln L ( θ ) E = I ( θ ) ∂θ∂θ ′ Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 20

  70. ML score and information • At the optimum there are two matrices we will use later in testing • The efficient score matrix is ∂ ln L ( θ ) = S ( θ ) ∂θ • This should be zero at ML estimate • The information matrix is given by � � − ∂ ln L ( θ ) E = I ( θ ) ∂θ∂θ ′ Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 20

  71. ML score and information • At the optimum there are two matrices we will use later in testing • The efficient score matrix is ∂ ln L ( θ ) = S ( θ ) ∂θ • This should be zero at ML estimate • The information matrix is given by � � − ∂ ln L ( θ ) E = I ( θ ) ∂θ∂θ ′ Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 20

  72. ML score and information • At the optimum there are two matrices we will use later in testing • The efficient score matrix is ∂ ln L ( θ ) = S ( θ ) ∂θ • This should be zero at ML estimate • The information matrix is given by � � − ∂ ln L ( θ ) E = I ( θ ) ∂θ∂θ ′ Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 20

  73. ML score and information • I ( θ ) turns out to be the most important matrix, as the Cram´ er-Rao lower bound states that − 1 Var (ˆ θ ml ) ≥ [ I (ˆ θ ml )] • This means that the covariance of an estimate exceeds the inverse of the information matrix by a positive semi-definite matrix • Thus the inverse provides the lower bound that an estimate can achieve! • Fortunately, a large number of ML estimators achieve this lower bound • I.e. in many cases it can be shown that the inverse of the information matrix is the covariance of the estimate er-Rao lower bound gives the covariance of ˆ • In those cases the Cram´ θ Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 21

  74. ML score and information • I ( θ ) turns out to be the most important matrix, as the Cram´ er-Rao lower bound states that − 1 Var (ˆ θ ml ) ≥ [ I (ˆ θ ml )] • This means that the covariance of an estimate exceeds the inverse of the information matrix by a positive semi-definite matrix • Thus the inverse provides the lower bound that an estimate can achieve! • Fortunately, a large number of ML estimators achieve this lower bound • I.e. in many cases it can be shown that the inverse of the information matrix is the covariance of the estimate er-Rao lower bound gives the covariance of ˆ • In those cases the Cram´ θ Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 21

  75. ML score and information • I ( θ ) turns out to be the most important matrix, as the Cram´ er-Rao lower bound states that − 1 Var (ˆ θ ml ) ≥ [ I (ˆ θ ml )] • This means that the covariance of an estimate exceeds the inverse of the information matrix by a positive semi-definite matrix • Thus the inverse provides the lower bound that an estimate can achieve! • Fortunately, a large number of ML estimators achieve this lower bound • I.e. in many cases it can be shown that the inverse of the information matrix is the covariance of the estimate er-Rao lower bound gives the covariance of ˆ • In those cases the Cram´ θ Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 21

  76. ML score and information • I ( θ ) turns out to be the most important matrix, as the Cram´ er-Rao lower bound states that − 1 Var (ˆ θ ml ) ≥ [ I (ˆ θ ml )] • This means that the covariance of an estimate exceeds the inverse of the information matrix by a positive semi-definite matrix • Thus the inverse provides the lower bound that an estimate can achieve! • Fortunately, a large number of ML estimators achieve this lower bound • I.e. in many cases it can be shown that the inverse of the information matrix is the covariance of the estimate er-Rao lower bound gives the covariance of ˆ • In those cases the Cram´ θ Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 21

  77. ML score and information • I ( θ ) turns out to be the most important matrix, as the Cram´ er-Rao lower bound states that − 1 Var (ˆ θ ml ) ≥ [ I (ˆ θ ml )] • This means that the covariance of an estimate exceeds the inverse of the information matrix by a positive semi-definite matrix • Thus the inverse provides the lower bound that an estimate can achieve! • Fortunately, a large number of ML estimators achieve this lower bound • I.e. in many cases it can be shown that the inverse of the information matrix is the covariance of the estimate er-Rao lower bound gives the covariance of ˆ • In those cases the Cram´ θ Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 21

  78. ML score and information • I ( θ ) turns out to be the most important matrix, as the Cram´ er-Rao lower bound states that − 1 Var (ˆ θ ml ) ≥ [ I (ˆ θ ml )] • This means that the covariance of an estimate exceeds the inverse of the information matrix by a positive semi-definite matrix • Thus the inverse provides the lower bound that an estimate can achieve! • Fortunately, a large number of ML estimators achieve this lower bound • I.e. in many cases it can be shown that the inverse of the information matrix is the covariance of the estimate er-Rao lower bound gives the covariance of ˆ • In those cases the Cram´ θ Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 21

  79. Asymptotic inference • We expect that any normalised statistic is distributed as √ θ − θ ) d n ( � → N ( 0 , I A (ˆ θ ) − 1 ) • Where I A ( θ ) − 1 = plim n I ( θ ) − 1 • Usually replace n I A ( θ ) − 1 by I ( θ ) − 1 • If we can formulate any statistic like this we know its distribution is χ 2 m with m the number of restrictions • Typically consider Wald (W), Likelihood ratio (LR) and LM statistics • Quick look at LR here Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 22

  80. Asymptotic inference • We expect that any normalised statistic is distributed as √ θ − θ ) d n ( � → N ( 0 , I A (ˆ θ ) − 1 ) • Where I A ( θ ) − 1 = plim n I ( θ ) − 1 • Usually replace n I A ( θ ) − 1 by I ( θ ) − 1 • If we can formulate any statistic like this we know its distribution is χ 2 m with m the number of restrictions • Typically consider Wald (W), Likelihood ratio (LR) and LM statistics • Quick look at LR here Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 22

  81. Asymptotic inference • We expect that any normalised statistic is distributed as √ θ − θ ) d n ( � → N ( 0 , I A (ˆ θ ) − 1 ) • Where I A ( θ ) − 1 = plim n I ( θ ) − 1 • Usually replace n I A ( θ ) − 1 by I ( θ ) − 1 • If we can formulate any statistic like this we know its distribution is χ 2 m with m the number of restrictions • Typically consider Wald (W), Likelihood ratio (LR) and LM statistics • Quick look at LR here Centre for Central Banking Studies Modelling and Forecasting 22

Recommend


More recommend