why open access is better for scholarly societies
play

Why open access is better for scholarly societies Stuart M. Shieber - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Why open access is better for scholarly societies Stuart M. Shieber Welch Professor of Computer Science School of Engineering and Applied Sciences Director Office for Scholarly Communication Harvard University Office for Scholarly


  1. Why open access is better for scholarly societies Stuart M. Shieber Welch Professor of Computer Science School of Engineering and Applied Sciences Director Office for Scholarly Communication Harvard University Office for Scholarly Communication 1 Harvard University

  2. Presented at the Symposium: Open Access and the Future of Academic Publishing at the 87th Annual Meeting of the Linguistic Society of America, Boston, MA, January 3, 2013. Author contact: Stuart M. Shieber Maxwell-Dworkin Laboratory — 245 Harvard University 33 Oxford Street Cambridge, MA 02138 shieber@seas.harvard.edu This work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution- Noncommercial-Share Alike 3.0 United States License. To view a copy of this license, visit http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-sa/3.0/ us/ or send a letter to Creative Commons, 171 Second Street, Suite 300, San Francisco, California, 94105, USA. Office for Scholarly Communication 2 Harvard University

  3. “ The Linguistic Society of America (LSA) was founded in 1924 to advance the scientific study of language . LSA plays a critical role in supporting and disseminating linguistic scholarship both to professional linguists and to the general public.” — Lingistic Society of America www.linguisticsociety.org Office for Scholarly Communication 3 Harvard University

  4. Economics of the subscription market • journals are complements , not substitutes Office for Scholarly Communication 4 Harvard University

  5. Office for Scholarly Communication 5 Harvard University

  6. Economics of the subscription market • journals are complements , not substitutes • limited market competition ➛ inefficiency Office for Scholarly Communication 6 Harvard University

  7. 1.5 commercial nonprofit 1.125 Price per page ($) 0.75 0.375 0 Ecology Economics Atmos. Sci. Mathematics Neuroscience Physics Ref: Carl Bergstrom, 2002, Journal pricing across disciplines. Office for Scholarly Communication 7 http://octavia.zoology.washington.edu/publishing/pageprice_table.html Harvard University

  8. 1.5 3 commercial nonprofit 1.125 2.25 Price per citation ($) Price per page ($) 1.5 0.75 0.75 0.375 0 0 Ecology Economics Atmos. Sci. Mathematics Neuroscience Physics Ecology Economics Atmos. Sci. Mathematics Neuroscience Physics Ref: Carl Bergstrom, 2002, Journal pricing across disciplines. Office for Scholarly Communication 7 http://octavia.zoology.washington.edu/publishing/pageprice_table.html Harvard University

  9. Economics of the subscription market • journals are complements , not substitutes • limited market competition ➛ inefficiency • access is a monopoly ➛ monopoly rents Office for Scholarly Communication 8 Harvard University

  10. Elsevier historical profit margin 40% 2,667 margin (%) revenue ($M) profit ($M) 30% 2,000 20% 1,334 10% 667 0% 0 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 Ref: Mike Taylor, The obscene profits of commercial scholarly publishers, 2012. Office for Scholarly Communication 9 http://bit.ly/VIJGPy Harvard University

  11. Economics of the subscription market • journals are complements , not substitutes • limited market competition ➛ inefficiency • access is a monopoly ➛ monopoly rents • pricing is controlled as a bundle ➛ cancellation futility ➛ hyperinflation Office for Scholarly Communication 10 Harvard University

  12. “ The immediate effect of [bundled pricing] has been to move competition from individual journals to large bundles of journals. ... Creating a large bundle of journals to compete with Elsevier or Kluwer seems almost insurmountable. ... There are indications that [bundled pricing] is hindering entry. Librarians ... say that they would spend more money for journals from smaller and alternative publishers if they could achieve proportionate savings from reductions. By selling electronic bundles, publishers have erected a strategic barrier to entry at just the time that the electronic publishing possibility has made it increasingly possible for alternative publishers to overcome the existing structural barriers.” — Edlin and Rubinfeld, “Exclusion or Efficient Pricing? The ‘Big Deal’ Bundling of Academic Journals” Office for Scholarly Communication 11 Harvard University

  13. Serials expenditures percentage increase over 1986 500% 400% serial expenditures %+ consumer price index %+ 300% 200% 100% 0% 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 Office for Scholarly Communication 12 Ref: ARL Statistics 2005-06, 07, 08 Harvard University

  14. 1.5 3 commercial nonprofit 1.125 2.25 Price per citation ($) Price per page ($) 1.5 0.75 0.75 0.375 0 0 Ecology Economics Atmos. Sci. Mathematics Neuroscience Physics Ecology Economics Atmos. Sci. Mathematics Neuroscience Physics Ref: Carl Bergstrom, 2002, Journal pricing across disciplines. Office for Scholarly Communication 13 http://octavia.zoology.washington.edu/publishing/pageprice_table.html Harvard University

  15. Economics of the subscription market • journals are complements , not substitutes • limited market competition ➛ inefficiency • access is a monopoly ➛ monopoly rents • pricing is controlled as a bundle ➛ cancellation futility ➛ hyperinflation Office for Scholarly Communication 14 Harvard University

  16. Economics of the publisher services market • journals are substitutes , not complements • enhanced market competition ➛ efficiency • service is a knowledge good ➛ low barrier to entry • pricing is controlled at the article ➛ market pricing ➛ competition Office for Scholarly Communication 15 Harvard University

  17. Revenue model comparison Subscription Fee Processing Fee moral hazard yes no good sold monopolistic competitive cross elasticity complement substitute cost per article $5,000 $1,200 Office for Scholarly Communication 16 Harvard University

  18. The Principle • Dissemination of research results is an inherent part of the research process. • The funders of research should underwrite dissemination of the results. Office for Scholarly Communication 17 Harvard University

  19. “ Each of the undersigned universities commits to the timely establishment of durable mechanisms for underwriting reasonable publication charges for articles written by its faculty and published in fee- based open-access journals and for which other institutions would not be expected to provide funds.” — Compact for Open-Access Publishing Equity www.oacompact.org Office for Scholarly Communication 18 Harvard University

  20. Signatories • University of Ottawa • Columbia University • Cornell University • Memorial Sloan-Kettering Cancer Center • Dartmouth College • University of Michigan and then • Harvard University • Universitat de Barcelona • Duke University • Massachusetts • University of Calgary Institute of Technology • Simon Fraser University • University of • CERN • Karlsruhe Institute of Technology California at Berkeley • University of Utah • University of Pittsburgh Office for Scholarly Communication 19 Harvard University

  21. What’s in our best interest? • Promote moves to open access • Allow self-archiving • Promote university OA policies • Accommodate university and funding agency policies • Support pro-OA legislation • Acquire some OA journals for experience • Push for OA underwriting by universities (COPE) and funding agencies Office for Scholarly Communication 20 Harvard University

  22. Harvard Office for Scholarly Communication osc.hul.harvard.edu Compact for Open-Access Publishing Equity oacompact.org The Occasional Pamphlet occasionalpamphlet.com Office for Scholarly Communication 21 Harvard University

Recommend


More recommend