political power and socio economic inequality
play

Political Power and Socio-Economic Inequality An Application of the - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

The Model Theoretical Analysis Simulation Results Political Power and Socio-Economic Inequality An Application of the Canonical Ensemble to Social Sciences Daniel Kraft July 25th, 2012 The Model Theoretical Analysis Simulation Results


  1. The Model Theoretical Analysis Simulation Results Political Power and Socio-Economic Inequality An Application of the Canonical Ensemble to Social Sciences Daniel Kraft July 25th, 2012

  2. The Model Theoretical Analysis Simulation Results Overview The Model 1 Theoretical Analysis 2 Simulation Results 3

  3. The Model Theoretical Analysis Simulation Results The Model

  4. The Model Theoretical Analysis Simulation Results Social Inequality “In 2010, average real income per family [in the United States] grew by 2.3 % but the gains were very uneven. Top 1 % incomes grew by 11.6 % while bottom 99 % incomes grew only by 0.2 %. Hence, the top 1 % captured 93 % of the income gains in the first year of recovery.”

  5. The Model Theoretical Analysis Simulation Results Social Inequality 1 Austria USA Turkey 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1

  6. The Model Theoretical Analysis Simulation Results The Social Space Individuals described by three dimensions :

  7. The Model Theoretical Analysis Simulation Results The Social Space Individuals described by three dimensions : Labour a ∈ [0 , 1] Income l ∈ [ L , ∞ ) to model the economy.

  8. The Model Theoretical Analysis Simulation Results The Social Space Individuals described by three dimensions : Power m ∈ [0 , 1] to model possibly unfair political decisions, and Labour a ∈ [0 , 1] Income l ∈ [ L , ∞ ) to model the economy.

  9. The Model Theoretical Analysis Simulation Results The Social Space Individuals described by three dimensions : Power m ∈ [0 , 1] to model possibly unfair political decisions, and Labour a ∈ [0 , 1] Income l ∈ [ L , ∞ ) to model the economy. Definition My social space: U = [0 , 1] × [0 , 1] × [ L , ∞ ) Individuals: x = ( m , p ) = ( m , a , l ) ∈ U

  10. The Model Theoretical Analysis Simulation Results Strain Functions Individuals try to maximise their personal happiness , respectively minimise their strain :

  11. The Model Theoretical Analysis Simulation Results Strain Functions Individuals try to maximise their personal happiness , respectively minimise their strain : Definition f : [0 , 1] × [ L , ∞ ) → R ∪ {∞} is a strictly convex strain function : f possesses certain regularity, f is strictly increasing in a and decreasing in l , and f is strictly convex.

  12. The Model Theoretical Analysis Simulation Results Strain Functions A note on convexity, a. k. a. decreasing marginal utility :

  13. The Model Theoretical Analysis Simulation Results Strain Functions A note on convexity, a. k. a. decreasing marginal utility : 0.4 0.35 0.3 0.25 Strain f 0.2 0.15 0.1 0.05 0 1 1.5 2 2.5 3 3.5 4 4.5 5 Labour l

  14. The Model Theoretical Analysis Simulation Results Strain Functions Indifference curves for f(a, l) = e a - log l 2 1.5 Income l 1 0.5 0 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 Labour a

  15. The Model Theoretical Analysis Simulation Results Coupling the Individuals Of course, single individuals do not yet form a society!

  16. The Model Theoretical Analysis Simulation Results Coupling the Individuals Of course, single individuals do not yet form a society! We require a closed economy : � N n =1 a n = � N n =1 l n Normalisation of powers: � N n =1 m n = 1

  17. The Model Theoretical Analysis Simulation Results Coupling the Individuals Of course, single individuals do not yet form a society! We require a closed economy : � N n =1 a n = � N n =1 l n Normalisation of powers: � N n =1 m n = 1 Definition Ω ⊂ U N is the set of all configurations X = ( x 1 , . . . , x N ) that satisfy these conditions. x i are the individuals in my social space.

  18. The Model Theoretical Analysis Simulation Results “Dynamics” of the System Definition We define the abstract energy H : Ω → R ∪ {∞} : � γ N � � H ( X ) = N + (1 − γ ) m n f ( a n , l n ) , n =1 where γ ∈ [0 , 1].

  19. The Model Theoretical Analysis Simulation Results “Dynamics” of the System Definition We define the abstract energy H : Ω → R ∪ {∞} : � γ N � � H ( X ) = N + (1 − γ ) m n f ( a n , l n ) , n =1 where γ ∈ [0 , 1]. Assume that the system tries to minimise H over Ω.

  20. The Model Theoretical Analysis Simulation Results “Dynamics” of the System 1 For a temperature T > 0 (or equivalently β = kT > 0) assume a Boltzmann distribution (canonical ensemble):

  21. The Model Theoretical Analysis Simulation Results “Dynamics” of the System 1 For a temperature T > 0 (or equivalently β = kT > 0) assume a Boltzmann distribution (canonical ensemble): Definition For A ⊂ Ω, define its probability as π T ( A ) = 1 � e − β H ( X ) dX , Z A where � e − β H ( X ) dX . Z = Ω

  22. The Model Theoretical Analysis Simulation Results Theoretical Analysis

  23. The Model Theoretical Analysis Simulation Results Structure of the Minimum Theorem Let γ = 1 . Then X ∈ Ω is a global minimum of H over Ω iff a n = l n = a ∗ , for all n = 1 , . . . , N . a ∗ is the minimum of a �→ f ( a , a ) over [ L , 1] .

  24. The Model Theoretical Analysis Simulation Results Structure of the Minimum Theorem Let γ = 1 . Then X ∈ Ω is a global minimum of H over Ω iff a n = l n = a ∗ , for all n = 1 , . . . , N . a ∗ is the minimum of a �→ f ( a , a ) over [ L , 1] . Theorem Let γ < 1 , then X ∗ ∈ Ω of the form X ∗ = ((1 , a ∗ 1 , l ∗ 1 ) , (0 , a ∗ 0 , l ∗ 0 ) , . . . , (0 , a ∗ 0 , l ∗ 0 )) minimises H over Ω . a ∗ 0 , a ∗ 1 ∈ [0 , 1] and l ∗ 0 , l ∗ 1 ≥ L depend on f and the parameters. This minimum is unique up to permutation of the individuals.

  25. The Model Theoretical Analysis Simulation Results A Simplified Problem � γ a 0 , l 0 , a 1 , l 1 γ N − 1 � min f ( a 0 , l 0 ) + N + (1 − γ ) f ( a 1 , l 1 ) , N where a 0 , a 1 ∈ [0 , 1], l 0 , l 1 ≥ L and ( N − 1) a 0 + a 1 = ( N − 1) l 0 + l 1 .

  26. The Model Theoretical Analysis Simulation Results A Simplified Problem � γ a 0 , l 0 , a 1 , l 1 γ N − 1 � min f ( a 0 , l 0 ) + N + (1 − γ ) f ( a 1 , l 1 ) , N where a 0 , a 1 ∈ [0 , 1], l 0 , l 1 ≥ L and ( N − 1) a 0 + a 1 = ( N − 1) l 0 + l 1 . Can be solved for instance by: Gradient projection techniques, or Newton’s method applied to the Lagrangian.

  27. The Model Theoretical Analysis Simulation Results A Simplified Problem 1 0.8 0.6 Income l 0.4 0.2 0 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 Labour a

  28. The Model Theoretical Analysis Simulation Results Further Results Consider the simplified problem. Theorem f ( a 1 , l 1 ) ≤ f ( a 0 , l 0 ) If γ < γ ′ , we also have f ( a 0 , l 0 ) ≥ f ( a ′ 0 , l ′ 0 ) and f ( a 1 , l 1 ) ≤ f ( a ′ 1 , l ′ 1 ) .

  29. The Model Theoretical Analysis Simulation Results Further Results Consider the simplified problem. Theorem f ( a 1 , l 1 ) ≤ f ( a 0 , l 0 ) If γ < γ ′ , we also have f ( a 0 , l 0 ) ≥ f ( a ′ 0 , l ′ 0 ) and f ( a 1 , l 1 ) ≤ f ( a ′ 1 , l ′ 1 ) . Let f be everywhere finite. Theorem The minimiser ( a 0 , l 0 , a 1 , l 1 ) ∈ R 4 depends continuously on γ .

  30. The Model Theoretical Analysis Simulation Results Further Results Consider the simplified problem. Theorem f ( a 1 , l 1 ) ≤ f ( a 0 , l 0 ) If γ < γ ′ , we also have f ( a 0 , l 0 ) ≥ f ( a ′ 0 , l ′ 0 ) and f ( a 1 , l 1 ) ≤ f ( a ′ 1 , l ′ 1 ) . Let f be everywhere finite. Theorem The minimiser ( a 0 , l 0 , a 1 , l 1 ) ∈ R 4 depends continuously on γ . Theorem If γ < 1 , we have a 0 > l 0 and a 1 < l 1 .

  31. The Model Theoretical Analysis Simulation Results Simulation Results

  32. The Model Theoretical Analysis Simulation Results Metropolis Algorithm Calculation of Z and expectation values intractable! → Numerical simulation, Monte-Carlo method

  33. The Model Theoretical Analysis Simulation Results Metropolis Algorithm Calculation of Z and expectation values intractable! → Numerical simulation, Monte-Carlo method Custom Metropolis algorithm: Generate configurations sampled by π T .

  34. The Model Theoretical Analysis Simulation Results Metropolis Algorithm Calculation of Z and expectation values intractable! → Numerical simulation, Monte-Carlo method Custom Metropolis algorithm: Generate configurations sampled by π T . Markov process, updating “current” configuration. We need P ( X ′ ) P ( X ) , but not P ( X ) directly. → Z drops out!

  35. The Model Theoretical Analysis Simulation Results Metropolis Algorithm Calculation of Z and expectation values intractable! → Numerical simulation, Monte-Carlo method Custom Metropolis algorithm: Generate configurations sampled by π T . Markov process, updating “current” configuration. We need P ( X ′ ) P ( X ) , but not P ( X ) directly. → Z drops out! This generates a “time series”, but does not imply anything about real time evolution!

  36. The Model Theoretical Analysis Simulation Results Energy Expectation 3 2 1 H 0 -1 1 0.8 -2 0.6 0 50 0.4 γ 100 0.2 150 β 0 200

  37. The Model Theoretical Analysis Simulation Results A Phase Transition Energy Histogram for β = 16.3 60000 50000 40000 Histogram Count 30000 20000 10000 0 -1 -0.5 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3 Energy H

  38. The Model Theoretical Analysis Simulation Results A Phase Transition 3.5 Left Phase Right Phase 3 2.5 2 Income l 1.5 1 0.5 0 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 Power m

Recommend


More recommend