making state aid
play

Making State Aid Work for Europes Decarbonisation State aid and - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Making State Aid Work for Europes Decarbonisation State aid and industry decarbonisation (Updated version: 21 January 2019) Juliette Delarue, ClientEarth Andreas Graf, Agora Energiewende BRUSSELS, 3 DECEMBER 2019 Objectives of the project


  1. EIIs receive measurable subsidies in the form of tax relief in FR, DE, GR, FI and SE. Support is less significant in other countries and in non-energy intensive industries Recoverable taxes and tax relieves paid by large industrial (energy intensive) and median level electricity customers in some EU Member States in 2016 Source: DG ENER, data from Trinomics et altri study (2018) 18

  2. Industry exemptions – Renewable energy support schemes 19

  3. Renewable energy support in Europe is significant and by far the largest intervention in energy markets in financial terms. Support to renewable energy sources in the EU Member States According to the State Aid Scoreboard, in 2018, Member States spent €97 billion on State aid. About 58% of total spending was attributed to State aid to environmental and energy savings, largely due to support for renewable energy sources (including energy tax reductions for energy-intensive users) According to CEER, in 2016, total supported renewable electricity reached 538 TWh, accounting for 16,7% of gross electricity production and costing €56.8 billion in support expenditure. A study for DG ENER estimates support for RES at €71 Billion in 2016. DG ENER, data from Trinomics et altri study (2018) 20

  4. Clean energy solutions have seen significant cost declines. Wind and solar are now generally cheaper than conventional and fossil technologies leading to a decline in support Cost reductions in major clean-energy technologies from 2008 – 2017 The cost for wind and solar has fallen dramatically over the last decade. They are now cheaper than any other new built power technology. More and more RES installations (the more expensive ones) are reaching the end of their support time. In most countries financial support levels for new renewable capacity has been lower than already supported or old plants that were substituted by new ones. In many cases, due to the design of support policies (e.g. feed-in-premiums), the current trend towards higher ETS carbon price may help to further reduce RES support costs. These trends will start to have a noticeable impact on the RES support cost developments in the coming years. NRDC (2018) Revolution now 21

  5. Private corporate renewable PPAs could play an increasing role in the sourcing of power for energy intensive industry, but are currently still a a niche market. Corporate Renewable Power Purchase Agreements (RES PPAs) are a private contract between a renewable energy generator and an end consumer, without an intermediary supplier. As they generally do not involve the State or public resources, they generally fall outside the scope of State aid control . RES PPAs could be an important tool for revenue stabilization of renewable energy operators while allowing energy intensive industries to source clean electricity at a fixed and competitive price. They come with certain benefits for generators to hedge the volatility of their revenues. To date, RES PPAs are still a niche market and not at the scale necessary to replace other policy driven revenue stabilisation mechanisms. The draft ETS State aid guidelines (released on 14 January 2020) include the contracting of RES/carbon-free PPAs amongst the options that EIIs can consider in order to be eligible to compensation for indirect costs ( conditionality ). This may result in an increase of these agreements in future. 22

  6. Potential barriers to corporate renewable PPAs Price risk linked to the uncertainty of future electricity price development and the long duration of PPAs represent the most prominent barriers to RE PPAs. So far (most) companies are willing to source renewable energy only if it does not cost more than conventional sourcing strategies. Implementation of ETS State Aid Guidelines on indirect cost compensation (e.g. Germany). Companies purchasing conventional electricity are compensated for part of the price they pay, whereas companies buying green electricity are not eligible to such compensation. Generators of renewable electricity have so far not been interested in signing PPAs because they were granted stable revenues by public support schemes providing a 100% protection from market risks (‘crowding - out effect’) . At the same time, without government guaranteed offtake, bank guarantees requested to off-takers can be very costly. Some MSs (eg. FR, DE) do not allow RES projects benefitting from public support schemes to receive guarantees of origin (GOs) over their production , while other MSs (e.g. NL, SE) allow companies to receive operational support for (eligible) RES production and claim GOs over the same production. This makes GOs a central item in RES PPA negotiations between project developers and off-takers. 23

  7. Challenge 1: Overcoming the „cost hill“ between 2018 to 2025 and dealing with legacy support costs from the previous higher support cost period. Guaranteed remuneration for renewable power plant owners, 2010 – 2035 70 80% Solar 68% 70% 60 Offshore Wind 59% 60% Onshore Wind RES-Share of consumption 50 Biomass 49% 50% Bill. Euro2019 Other 40 41% 40% Solar (stock) 31,0 33,1 30 30% Offshore Wind (stock) 30% 24,6 27,6 Onshore Wind (stock) 17,9 20 18% 20% Biomass (stock) 14,2 10 Other (stock) 10% 0 0% RES-Share in gross power consumption Own projection based on Öko-Institut (2019) 24

  8. In Germany, even the sum of wholesale electricity price and EEG-levy should decline by 2022 at the latest. Electricity price (rolling annual future price for base load) and EEG levy, 2010 – 2035 12,0 12,5 11,0 11,5 11,5 11,5 11,4 11,2 10,8 10,4 10,0 9,7 10,9 11,1 10,2 9,8 9,7 10,1 9,8 9,5 10,0 9,3 8,6 8,3 8,1 ct/kWh (2019) 7,0 7,8 7,8 6,1 5,9 7,7 6,3 5,7 5,6 6,7 5,2 4,8 3,9 6,4 4,4 6,6 4,0 7,5 3,9 3,5 EEG-levy 2,8 2,3 6,5 2,2 1,9 1,8 1,7 6,8 6,6 7,0 Power price 5,0 Sum power price + 6,0 6,0 6,0 6,0 5,8 5,9 5,9 levy 5,7 5,8 5,6 5,6 5,6 5,7 5,4 5,5 5,5 5,4 5,2 2,5 5,1 4,9 4,6 4,4 3,7 3,2 3,2 2,7 0,0 Own projection based on Öko-Institut (2019) 25

  9. Challenge 2: Taxes, levies & surcharges on electricity are often high in comparison to those placed on fossil fuels in heating & transport (disincentive for electrification), Challenge 3: Fair distribution btw. consumers Electricity cost components (ct/kWh) for different German Energy-related regulated cost components for German households consumers types 25 VAT 23,0 EEG-Surcharge 20 17,0 17,0 Other levies 15 ct/kWh CO 2 -Certificates 8,7 10 ( ≙ 20 €/EUA) 5,6 Concession Fee 5 2,7 0,7 Network charges 0 Consumption EV, PtX Heat pump, PtX Natural gas Heating oil Energy tax Diesel Petrol Electricity tax Power Transport Heat Agora Energiewende (2018) Source: AEE (2014) based on BDEW, Eurostat, BNetzA 26 29.05.2019

  10. Funding of RES support schemes In principle there are two main approaches to the funding of RES support schemes: • 1) General taxation • 2) Non-tax levies paid via the electricity bill by some or all electricity consumers. A recent CEER Survey found that most countries fund their RES support schemes through non-tax levies (21 out of 27 responses). Four countries (Denmark, Finland, Luxembourg, and Malta) collect funds for the support costs by general taxation paid by all citizens. For example, since January 2016, renewables support in France falls under the general State budget, through a dedicated purpose fund – the financing of which being decided each year by the Parliament through a Finance Law (currently, internal taxes on fossil fuels).

  11. Exemptions from financing RES support schemes Often there are exemptions (partial or full) to the financing contributions, which may increase the financial burden for non-exempted consumers. A recent CEER Survey found that most countries apply one or more types of exemptions: • Exemptions for energy intensive industries (12 of 27). • Exemptions for self-generated electricity from RES or conventional plants on site (9 of 27). • Other types of exemptions include partial or full exemption of low-income households (Austria), households and small enterprises (Hungary); captive users (Latvia); and consumers that have agreed to certain energy efficiency improvements (Netherlands). No explicit exemptions but costs socialised through the state budget (Malta). No explicit exemptions scheme (Ireland, Spain and Cyprus) 28

  12. Reductions in funding support for electricity from RES – Compatibility criteria • Need to demonstrate that the additional costs reflected in higher electricity prices faced by the beneficiary only result from the support to RES • Eligibility: • Be included in the list of sectors which competitive position is affected due to their electro- intensity (EI) and exposure to international trade (Annex 3 EEAG) Or having an EI > 20% and belonging to a sector with a trade intensity > 4% • Objective, non-discriminatory and transparent criteria, and equality • • Proportionality: beneficiaries shall pay > 15% of the funding without reduction • Form of the aid: reduction from charges and/or fixed annual compensation amount (tax refund) 29

  13. Case studies / Specific points As opposed to some countries that have limited the eligibility of indirect compensation costs to part of the eligible EIIs list (UK, NL), no such limitation of EIIs eligible within Annex III EEAG was found for exemptions from renewable support. In its ruling of 28 March 2019, the CJEU found that the support scheme to RES provided for in the German EEG 2012 did not constitute State aid as suppliers were not under an obligation to collect levies from end-consumers. However there is no examination of the reductions for EIIs whereas there are also elements of State control: the reductions are compulsory and set by law. 30

  14. Reflections Exemptions from support to RES for EIIs are found in nearly all MS that have a RES support scheme in place. Exemptions for other consumers exist, but are less commonly applied. In some cases (notably Germany), financing RES support via levies has raised significant distributional concerns and provided perverse disincentives for electrification. These concerns are further amplified by exemptions for electro-intensive industry. A shift to financing RES support or exemptions via the overall state budget – potentially using revenues from CO2 pricing – could reduce the regressive and distortive effects of taxes, levies and surcharges on electricity consumption, but is currently used by few countries to significant effect. To provide an incentive for corporate RES procurement, the EEAG could factor in energy procurement strategies, notably corporate renewable Power Purchase Agreements, amongst the conditions for exemptions from the renewable energy surcharges , as proposed in the draft ETS State aid guidelines released on 14 January 2020 for indirect costs compensation. In the context of future renewable revenue stabilisation mechanisms, state aid guidelines should allow for revenues for RES PPA to stand in conjunction other RES support – eg. in the form of renewable Contracts for Difference – to enable business models and reduce financing costs. 31

  15. Indirect cost compensation under the EU ETS 32

  16. Power markets can magnify the consumer cost of CO 2 pricing Merit Order and Electricity Price Increase With CO2 Price Estimating indirect costs is difficult, but power markets can magnify the consumer cost of CO 2 When a carbon price is applied and where the marginal power plant is fossil-fueled, the clearing price increases and all generators in the stack receive additional income. The extra rent paid to generators, owing to the carbon price raising the wholesale electricity price, passes through to consumer bills. Source: RAP 33

  17. In 2019, prices for coal, oil and gas decreased, while the price of CO 2 certificates reached the highest level seen in the past 10 years Import prices for natural gas, hard coal, and oil, as well as CO 2 certificate prices 60 55,3 Cross-border prices and CO 2e -certificate 52,6 51,0 prices (EUR/MWh_th or EUR/t CO 2e ) 47,7 50 41,6 38,8 38,3 36,8 40 30,8 30,6 29,0 27,9 27,6 26,8 30 25,7 24,6 24,6 23,5 20,9 20,6 20,6 19,3 17,0 20 16,3 15,4 22,3 14,3 13,1 13,1 14,8 11,4 11,3 9,7 9,0 8,9 8,3 8,2 10 13,8 13,1 11,7 10,5 9,7 7,6 7,3 5,9 5,8 5,3 0 4,4 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019* Hard coal (EUR/MWh) Natural gas (EUR/MWh) Oil (EUR/MWh) CO2-Price (EUR/t CO2) Federal Office for Economic Affairs and Export Control (2019), Deutsche Emissionshandelsstelle (2019), own calculations, *preliminary results 34

  18. Due to these higher CO 2 prices gas plants have in many cases become as profitable as hard coal and even old lignite plants Marginal costs for new natural-gas power plants and old power plants fired with lignite and hard coal 60 51,7 53,0 48,2 48,0 54,6 50 Marginal cost (EUR/MWh_el) 43,9 41,9 42,8 39,8 39,8 37,5 40 45,0 36,0 33,9 32,0 39,2 37,7 36,1 27,9 34,9 35,6 30 30,8 22,7 22,2 20,8 20,7 28,7 28,1 27,9 25,7 20 13,9 13,6 11,9 11,6 11,0 10,0 10 0 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019* Lignite (old, 33%) Hard coal (old, 39%) Natural gas (new, 58%) Federal Office for Economic Affairs and Export Control (2019), Deutsche Emissionshandelsstelle (2019/2006), Öko-Institut (2017), efficiency factor in brackets, *own calculations/preliminary data 35

  19. At the same time, higher renewables generation is helping to mitigate the increase in wholesale prices from CO 2 - pricing due to the ‘merit order effect’ Merit-Order-Effects Demand Demand EUR/MWh EUR/MWh Price Price MW MW MW Own illustration 36

  20. Electricity consumers in some Member States are thus more strongly impacted by a rise in CO 2 prices than others due to differences in generation mix. Comparison of wholesale power prices in selected European neighbouring countries Own calculations based on ENTSO-E (2019), Mercato Elettrico (2019), Nordpool (2019), TGE (2019), OTE (2019), 30.12.19 37

  21. In the past years, energy costs have actually come down in sectors being shielded from indirect electricity costs. Evolution of the energy cost shares over time of select EEI sectors, 2008-2015 From 2010-2015, energy costs fell substantially among a number of energy intensive 25.00% industries, including in Manufacture of cement, lime and plaster , Manufacture of basic iron and steel and of ferro-alloys and Manufacture of Cement, lime and plaster 20.00% man-made fibres, where energy costs fell by Mining of metal ores over 25% between 2010-2015; Energy Cost Share (%) Clay building materials Pulp and paper 15.00% The largest percentage point decline in cost Glass share can be observed in the cement, lime and Iron and steel plaster with a decline in cost share from around Man-made fibres 10.00% 23% to 16% observed (-7%). Basic chemicals Porcelain and ceramics Manufacture of abrasive products and Non-ferrous metals nonmetallic mineral products , Manufacture of 5.00% Plastics products other porcelain and ceramic products and Sawmilling and planing of wood s aw increases resulting from higher energy prices and gross 0.00% 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 output outpacing cost savings due to energy Trinomics (2019): Study on Energy Prices, Costs and Subsidies and their intensity improvements. Impact on Industry and Households - Annexes to the Final report 38

  22. However, the price of futures has been on an upward trend since 2017 in part due to higher CO 2 -prices Rolling annual future prices 2007 to 2019 140 120 Power exchange price €/MWh 100 80 69,9 55,9 56,0 60 49,9 49,2 49,2 47,7 44,2 39,1 35,1 32,4 40 31,0 26,6 20 0 Jan Jul Okt Jan Jul Okt Jan Jul Okt Jan Jul Okt Jan Jul Okt Jan Jul Okt Jan Jul Okt Jan Jul Okt Jan Jul Okt Jan Jul Okt Jan Jul Okt Jan Jul Okt Jan Jul Okt Apr Apr Apr Apr Apr Apr Apr Apr Apr Apr Apr Apr Apr 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 Baseload Peakload Mean Baseload Own calculations based on EEX (2019, as of 30.12.19) 39

  23. Moreover, market future prices indicate that even higher electricity prices are expected by 2025. 2019 future prices for power delivery in 2020 – 2024 60 Power exchange price for the respective 55 50 delivery period (EUR/MWh) 45 40 35 30 25 20 15 01.01.2019 16.01.2019 31.01.2019 15.02.2019 02.03.2019 17.03.2019 01.04.2019 16.04.2019 01.05.2019 16.05.2019 31.05.2019 15.06.2019 30.06.2019 15.07.2019 30.07.2019 14.08.2019 29.08.2019 13.09.2019 28.09.2019 13.10.2019 28.10.2019 12.11.2019 27.11.2019 12.12.2019 27.12.2019 Trading day 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024 2025 EEX (2019, as of 30.12.19) 40

  24. Thus, while often marginal today, it is possible that higher climate ambition will increase the impact of indirect CO2 costs on competitiveness In many cases today, the carbon price may be marginal in the composition of production costs for an exempted company - other factors influence a company’s choice of location, such market proximity, quality of infrastructure, expertise in research and development and respect of the rule of law, to mention a few. At the same time, to reach a -55% GHG target a significant revision of the EU ETS Directive and greater electrification would be needed, which could lead to significantly higher ETS prices. It is thus reasonable to expect that electricity intensive industries will experience higher indirect costs with EU allowances (EUA) prices on the rise. 41

  25. Compatibility rules on indirect cost compensation in the ETS State aid Guidelines (2012) ETS Directive: direct costs are compensated through free allowances, while compensation for indirect costs remains optional through State aid at the discretion of Member States. Article 10a(6) : Member States may adopt financial measures in favour of sectors exposed to a significant risk of carbon leakage due to “indirect emissions costs”. Indirect emissions costs refer to costs relating to GHG emissions passed on in electricity prices. The Guidelines on certain State aid measures in the context of the greenhouse gas emission allowance trading scheme post-2012 explain when Member States may compensate electro- intensive undertakings active in a sector exposed to international trade, for part of the higher electricity costs resulting from the EU ETS. Under the revised ETS Directive, Member States may continue to grant operating aid to compensate indirect emission costs. However, the ETS guidelines are being revised for the fourth trading period starting on 1 January 2021. A targeted consultation of the interested sectors took place from January to April 2019 to gather information on which sectors are exposed to carbon leakage risk. Draft guidelines were released for consultation on 14 January 2020 with a list of eligible sectors reduced by half. 42

  26. Eligible aid measures and beneficiaries (2012 ETS guidelines) Eligible sectors for indirect cost compensation Only beneficiaries active in sectors and subsectors explicitly listed in Annex II of the ETS Guidelines are considered at significant risk of carbon leakage and thus eligible for state aid. 13 sectors and 7 subsectors were eligible in phase 3, including non-ferrous metals, textiles, chemicals, paper, basic iron and steel, plastics, and a number of mining sectors. Eligible sectors are defined using quantitative and qualitative criteria. Quantitative criteria include trade intensity with third countries (above 10%) and indirect costs that would increase production costs (Share of GVA of at least 5%) for automatic selection. Qualitative criteria are used for sectors with missing or low quality data. Source: ERCST Presentation (2019) Sectors remaining in the draft guidelines of14 January 2020 are highlighted in yellow. 43

  27. Maximum aid intensity and digression Compensation for installations is limited by the ‘maximum aid intensity’ based on a formula: 𝑩𝒏𝒃𝒚𝒖 = 𝑩𝒋𝒖 ∗ 𝑫𝒖 ∗ 𝑸𝒖 − 𝟐 ∗ 𝑭 ∗ 𝑪 O • 𝑩𝒏𝒃𝒚𝒖 is the maximum aid intensity in year t 𝑩𝒋𝒖 is the aid intensity at year t, expressed as a fraction which decreases over time (75% in 2019) • • 𝑫𝒖 is the applicable CO2 emission factor (tCO2 /MWh) (at year t) • 𝑸𝒖 − 𝟐 is the EUA forward price at year t-1 (EUR/tCO2 ) • 𝑭 is the applicable product-specific electricity consumption efficiency benchmark; and • 𝑪𝑷 is the baseline output. 44

  28. Maximum aid intensity and digression Aid is set to decline degressively over time. The digression for the maximum share of eligible costs that could be provided via state aid started at 85% (2013-2015) and declined progressively to 80% (2016-2018) and 75% (2019-2020), respectively. The draft revised guidelines provide for a stable aid intensity of 75%. Within these boundaries , each Member State can freely decide whether to put in place State aid measures or not , and to what extent. Under Art. 10(6) of the ETS Directive: 1) Ex ante (sub-)sectoral benchmarks are to be used for calculation of carbon leakage risk; and 2) Member States shall also seek to use no more than 25 % of the revenues generated from the auctioning of allowances for indirect cost compensation; otherwise they must publish a report setting out the reasons. Under Art. 30 of the Directive, Commission will review international developments and may consider whether measures in relation to the compensation of indirect costs should be further harmonised. 45

  29. State aid cases / review Indirect costs compensation and total auction revenues – 2016 and 2017 In 2018, 11 Member States and Norway provided compensation for indirect costs. Luxembourg and Wallonia (BE) have recently been approved by the Commission and political agreements have recently been reached in the Czech Republic and Poland. The most recent data available on cost compensation is for the years 2016 and 2017. This data shows that there are big differences between Member States, which can largely be explained by the emissions intensity of their power production relative to auction revenues. This is compared with the percentage of auction revenues it represents. According to the revised EU ETS Directive, Member States should seek to compensate for maximum 25% of their auctioning revenues or must publish a Source: 2019 State of EU ETS Report (ERCST, I4CE, EcoAct, ICIS and report explaining why they exceeded that %. Wegener Centre) 46

  30. State Aid Case Studies / Restricting eligibility Some MS limited eligibility to the scheme by adding criteria filtering within Annex II ETS Guidelines UK (2013): EII which carbon costs (EU ETS and CPF taken together) in 2020 will amount to 5% of their gross value added. “Even within the EII sectors, there may be some processes which use much less electricity and will be less exposed to electricity price increases.” Flanders (2013) and Netherlands (2013): EIIs must have in place an agreement committing them to certain measures to improve energy efficiency . These agreements are not specific to this aid scheme. They are linked to tax reductions on the consumption of energy products that can be granted under Article 17 of the Energy Tax Directive. They are open to all and not discriminatory. COM: “A Member State is not obliged to grant aid to all sectors , subsectors or even installations belonging to these sectors or subsectors. Rather, the Member State’s authorities may decide to further restrict the scope of eligible applicants. As long as such a restriction does not contradict or run counter to the ETS Guidelines, nor results in the breaching of any provision of EU law, and in particular as long as it is based on objective criteria , the Member State may opt for such a restriction.” 47

  31. State Aid Case Studies / Going beyond the ETS guidelines Consumption threshold of 1GWh/y in NL, DE, FI, SK “to avoid disproportionate administrative burden” Finland (2017): The maximum aid intensity is 50% of the maximum aid intensities allowed by the Guidelines for the same year. In consequence, the maximum aid intensities are 40% of the eligible costs incurred in 2016, 2017 and 2018 and 37.5% of the eligible costs incurred in 2019 and 2020, in line with point 26 of the Guidelines. Wallonia (2018): Obligation to repay the aid if the beneficiary relocates outside the EU within 5 years of the payment of aid. Monitoring and effective enforcement of this obligation remain doubtful in particular in case of progressive relocations of the industries that are difficult to control. 48

  32. State Aid Case Studies / RES Procurement Current guidelines state that no State aid can be granted ‘in case of electricity supply contracts that do not include any CO2 costs’. If electricity prices are set through merit order, then 100% renewable contracts also pass through ‘opportunity’ CO2 costs. Some anecdotal evidence exists that this has disincentivized industry to engage in 100% RE contracts in Germany as Germany’s implementation of the guidelines risks them missing out on state aid. By contrast, in Finland, in order to demonstrate that aid is only granted for electricity including CO2 costs in its price, the applicant needs to show that the electricity could be sold to a third party in the market place and at market price by demonstrating that it has the readiness to do it and it is technically possible. This interpretation does not seem to create this challenge and seems to be in line with the current state-aid guidelines, as approved by the Commission. Has indirect cost compensation provided a perverse disincentive for RES procurement or just the implementation of the guidelines in Germany? 49

  33. Reflections Indirect cost passthrough is difficult to establish methodologically, in particular given the countervailing effects of renewables deployment on electricity prices. Policy objectives to be balanced include 1. carbon leakage risk mitigation for electro-intensive industry; 2. risk of overcompensation and windfall profits, harming other consumers; 3. risk of internal market distortions within, or between, sectors; 4. Incentivizing cost-efficient decarbonization. The ETS Guidelines are designed to provide a minimum level of coherence between Member State schemes on the sectors supported and the size of State aid permissible, but are not uniformly implemented due to Member State discretion. Thus, it is unclear to what extent this goal is met. In absolute volumes, indirect cost compensation granted by Member States is much smaller in financial terms compared to exemptions for renewables support or direct support through free allocation. However, these volumes could increase with higher climate ambition. Interpretation of the current guidelines may perversely disincentivize corporate RES procurement through PPAs in the case of Germany, but is not seemingly an issue in other countries. Thus it is unclear to what extent the Guidelines would be improved through clearer language. 50

  34. New draft COM Guidelines (14.1.2019) – Stated Objectives The draft Guidelines proposed for consultation need to address three specific objectives: • minimising the risk of carbon leakage, • preserving the EU ETS objective to achieve cost-efficient decarbonisation and • minimising competition distortions in the internal market. The Commission will make sure that the Guidelines: • “remain consistent with, and contribute to, all relevant climate -related policy instruments that will be proposed in the context of the Green Deal to ensure effective carbon pricing throughout the economy, while respecting a level playing field.” Source: COM Explanatory note (2019) 51

  35. New draft COM Guidelines (14.1.2019) – Main Changes Reduces number of eligible sectors from 13 to 8 Instead of digression, maximum aid intensity is to remain constant at 2020 levels (75%). The draft Guidelines proposed for consultation also introduce the possibility for Member States to further limit the exposure of beneficiaries to indirect ETS cost as a function of their gross value added (“GVA”). A mid-term update of the electricity consumption efficiency benchmarks will be performed, based on the most efficient methods of production for the product considered. Moreover, the methodology for updating these benchmarks is to be updated to extrapolate and annual reduction rate. Baseline output will be calculated based on actual as opposed to historical emissions. Compensation will be conditional to decarbonisation efforts, in particular with regards to energy efficiency. 52

  36. New draft COM Guidelines (14.1.2019) – Conditionality Compensation will be conditional to decarbonisation efforts, including conducting energy audits, and: • Implementing energy audit recommendations, OR • Investing a significant share (> 80%) of the aid amount in projects that lead to substantial reductions of the installation’s greenhouse gas emissions and well below the applicable benchmark used for free allocation in the EU ETS, OR • Reducing the carbon footprint of their electricity consumption (eg. via onsite RES or a RES PPA). Member States would have to verify that beneficiaries, irrespective of their size, have conducted or commit to conduct an energy audit or have an energy or environmental management system in place. Member States would also have to monitor the implementation of the resulting recommendations by large undertakings. The Commission as part of its monitoring efforts for approved schemes can check compliance with this requirement. Source: COM Explanatory note (2019) 53

  37. New draft COM Guidelines (14.1.2019) – Included sectors Sectors deemed exposed to a genuine risk of carbon leakage due to indirect costs: • Manufacture of leather clothes; Aluminium production; Manufacture of other inorganic basic chemicals; Lead, zinc and tin production; Manufacture of pulp; Manufacture of paper and paperboard; Manufacture of basic iron and steel and ferro- alloys; Manufacture of refined petroleum products. Removed sectors: • Mining of chemical and fertiliser minerals; Manufacture of fertilisers and nitrogen compounds; Copper production; Manufacture of other organic basic chemicals; Spinning of cotton-type fibres; Manufacture of man-made fibres Source: COM Explanatory note (2019) 54

  38. New draft COM Guidelines (14.1.2019) – Formula for calculating eligible aid The formula for calculating the eligible aid amount remains largely the same with some exceptions: • The baseline output used for the purposes of the calculation will in future correspond to the actual production in the year preceding the granting of the aid (as opposed the average historical output over the reference period 2005-2011). • The electricity consumption efficiency benchmarks will be updated at the beginning and in the middle of the next ETS trading period and the actual regional CO2 factors must still be set. In 2025, the Commission will also assess whether additional data is available allowing to improve and revise the methodology used to calculate the CO2 emission factors, i.e. to take into account the increasingly important price-setting role of low-carbon technologies in EU electricity markets. Source: COM Explanatory note (2019) 55

  39. Industry exemptions – Other topics of relevance 56

  40. Reflections on other regimes of exemptions for EIUs Environmental taxation in the non-ETS sector : Are negotiated agreements credible? What use of the simplified approach in Section 3.7.1 EEAG since Article 44 GBER covers exemption from energy taxes with no threshold? Carbon price floor (UK) : The exemption is compatible with the EEAG. Funding of capacity mechanism (Poland) : Critics relate to dis-incentive for EIUs from reducing consumption in peak hours and distributional effects of this novel scheme. Energy efficiency obligations schemes : New exemptions to come? Grid / network charges (Germany) : Full exemption from network charges is incompatible. 57

  41. Reflections - Environmental Taxation in the Non-ETS Sectors Taxation remains a Member State competence, but some State aid principles (eg. Environmental taxation) and harmonized legislation (eg. the Energy Taxation Directive) apply. Efficient decarbonization of the non-ETS sectors will require CO 2 -oriented energy tax reform for heating and transport fuels on EU or MS level. A reform of the Energy Taxation Directive, envisaged in the Green Deal, could play an important role in harmonizing minimum energy taxation based on CO2 intensity across Europe. The ability to exempt trade exposed energy intensive industries from part or most of these costs is likely to be critical to gaining support for a revision of the Energy Taxation Directive and domestic tax reforms, but could raise concerns about internal market distortions and cost distributions, as already highlighted by the recent COM evaluation of the ETD. Harmonised taxes under Energy Taxation Directive: What use of the simplified approach in Section 3.7.1 EEAG since Article 44 GBER covers them with no notification threshold? Non-harmonised taxes : Are the negotiated agreements credible? Is monitoring adequate? 58

  42. Reflections – Industry exemptions under a carbon price floor While not eliminating the need for a robust enabling framework for clean energy investments, a Carbon Price Floor under the EU-ETS would create investment certainty by reducing risks for investors in clean energy technologies. State aid questions are raised by concerns over the need to exempt energy intensive industry from the costs resulting from higher ambition. Exemptions for EII under the UK CPF suggest that the current EEAG enable these exemptions in the case of a surrender charge. For an EU-wide CPF implemented via an Auction Reserve Price, the ETS State Aid Guidelines and system of indirect cost compensation would apply. 59

  43. Reflections – Exemptions from funding capacity mechanisms Poland plans to reduce the capacity mechanism surcharge that ≈ 350 energy intensive users have to pay for energy consumed during peak hours. Commission opened a formal investigation on 15 April 2019 > final decision awaited No compatibility criteria in the EEAG > general rule of Article 107(3) TFEU Foreseeable consequences of a reduction in capacity mechanism surcharge: • Lack of incentive of EIUs to reduce consumption and/or to shift production outside peak hours > increase / maintains need for a capacity mechanism; • Increase financial burden on small consumers (businesses & households) Chances of success: Why is Poland the only MS trying its luck? Data: the opening decision demonstrates the Commission’s lack of data for a critical assessment of such a scheme that is ”novel in both its subject matter and its implications for the future”. 60

  44. Reflections – Release of costs of energy efficiency obligations schemes? “Member States shall assess and, if appropriate, take measures to minimise the impact of the direct and indirect costs of energy efficiency obligation schemes on the competitiveness of energy- intensive industries exposed to international competition.” (art. 7a EED) New form of reduction/exemption for EIIs, not currently in the EEAG > assessment on a case by case basis pending the revision of the EEAG. Will the eligible industries be the same as in Annex III EEAG, by analogy? What will be an acceptable aid intensity / level of reduction of costs? How to incentivise these EIUs, which shall be the main target of energy efficiency schemes, to realise the adequate investment in energy efficiency? Giving them investment aid + exonerating them from the costs of energy efficiency obligation schemes is counter-productive. Agreements with MS with energy efficiency targets are a poor fall-back solution. 61

  45. Reflections – Exemptions from network charges Germany fully exempted baseload consumers from network charges in 2011- 2013 (≈ 200 EIUs) Complaint by consumer associations, energy companies and citizens Final decision after formal investigation (6 March 2013 - 28 May 2018) • No aid in 2011 ≠ State resources involved in 2012 -2013 (levy) Network charges are a typical part of electricity costs that users have to pay: price for using a • service • No objective justification for a full exemption: EIUs generate network costs, even if lower due to their stable consumption profile • Increase the financial burden on other electricity users • Incompatible with the Treaty & monies need to be recovered Court actions: no state resource; no selective advantage; unequal treatment 62

  46. Reflections – Exemptions from a climate levy or a carbon price on end-products Recent studies have proposed financing policy instruments for decarbonizing the industry sector – eg. Carbon Contracts for Difference (CCfDs – covered in Part II) – via a climate contribution based on the carbon intensity of basic materials or a carbon price on end-products. Where these instruments would be implemented on a national basis and exemptions were granted to specific industries – instead of EU-wide with exemptions granted via free-allocation and indirect cost compensation under the EU ETS – these would have to go through separate state aid approval. 63

  47. Discussion 64

  48. Lunch Break 65

  49. Part II – Support for industry decarbonization 66

  50. Climate-neutral industry The Agora-Industry-Trilogy 67

  51. Smart industry decarbonisation policy requires a policy-mix Illustration of the climate policy-mix, and principles for a Climate Change Act Carbon pricing allows you to find the cheapest emissions abatement options ( efficiency ) and 400 get the most out of your actions ( effectiveness ) breakthrough 8 Innovations technologies close to However, measures on the left and right end of market competitiveness 200 10 Euro/t CO 2e the abatement cost curve are currently barely 4 13 12 2, 7 & 8 7 deployed, mainly due to such factors as: 10 12 7 & 8 12 9 2 & 9 8 5 12 6 14 • Long-term planning requirements 0 4 14 2 & 9 12 4 • Technological developments 12 • International competition 12 economic, but untapped -200 2,10 & 11 potential 300 400 • Non-price barriers 2 Carbon pricing outside the EU ETS 9 Bonus/Malus system for car purchases Mt CO 2e Infrastructure • 4 Adjust the EEG 10 Reforming the truck toll system 5 Putting the coal exit into law 11 Promoting a mobility transition in cities 6 immediate program green district heat 12 Investments into energy efficiency in industry Therefore, standards and additional policy 7 Ambitious building standards 13 A quota for green hydrogen 8 Tax incentives for building refurbishment 14 Enable market penetration of low carbon measures (eg. subsidies) are necessary illustrative breakthhough technologies in industry complements to a CO 2 price, in particular in the case of industry decarbonization. Source: own illustration based on BDI (2018) and Matthes (2010) 68

  52. Why a policy mix? The marginal abatement costs of many breakthrough innovations are significantly higher than current EU ETS-prices Marginal abatement costs of new technologies in industry 2030, lower range, in Euro/t CO 2 Sources: Wuppertal Institute/Agora, 2019 69

  53. Why a policy mix? All plants built today will still exist in 2050 – any future investment must therefore be Paris-compatible Technical lifetime of primary production plants in the steel, chemical and cement sectors with reinvestment in 2025 Sources: Agora Energiewende/Wuppertal Institute, 2019 70

  54. Why a policy mix? Until 2030 there is a very high need for reinvestment in the energy-intensive industry - many jobs are affected Reinvestment needs in German Industry until 2030 (primary Direct employment of relevant industries in Germany 2018 production capacity) Source: Wuppertal Institute, 2019 Source: Statistisches Bundesamt, 2018

  55. The transformation will take place within established companies – this requires a rapid phase-in of the new technologies Transformation of the portfolio of an energy-intensive company (indicative presentation) Source: Agora Energiewende, 2019 72

  56. A number of policy instruments are available to support industry decarbonization. Upstream-Midstream-Downstream-Regulation Upstream Mechanism for internationally competitive energy prices Feed-in quota for green hydrogen Access to raw material (including from recycling) Midstream EU-ETS / Carbon pricing Carbon Contracts for Difference (direct support) Green financing Downstream Green material quota CO 2 -price for final products Circular economy standards Agora Energiewende Building codes that reduce steel an cement use 73

  57. Carbon Contracts for Difference (CCfD) 74

  58. Background Most promising breakthrough industrial decarbonization technologies require high investment and operational expenditures compared to conventional technologies. As it currently stands the carbon price in the EU ETS will not create sufficient incentives for investment. Due to the high variability of the CO2-price in the EU ETS and its high risk of policy change, these technologies are also marked by higher financing risks compared to established technologies. The price signal of the EU ETS can provide efficiency improvements in current operations, but is insufficient for providing the investment security needed for innovative technologies and cover the incremental costs associated with them. Under these circumstances little has been invested in innovative low-emissions breakthrough technologies thus far. Therefore, in particular for capital-intensive innovative low-carbon processes and alternative materials, carbon pricing needs to be complemented in the short term by other policies that create lead markets and hedge against regulatory risk, as well as trigger incentives in the value chain. 75

  59. What is a Carbon Contract for Difference (CCfD)? CCfDs can be used to provide project-specific support for operational expenditures for breakthrough technologies needed for the long-term greenhouse gas reduction of heavy industry (eg. Steel, Cement, Chemicals), while orienting the support towards the EU ETS price. CCfDs are contracts between national governments and companies developing a low-carbon project, which reimburse the difference between the yearly average price of EU ETS emission allowances (EUAs) and an agreed strike price per ton of emission reduction. In turn, companies are obliged to pay back the previously received funding in case ETS prices exceed the strike price. Project-based CCfDs create lead markets for innovative low-carbon production processes and materials at national and European scale. By determining a fixed project-based strike price, a CCfD provides a guaranteed carbon price, thus ensuring that that the incremental operating costs of the project are covered so that the project can continue to operate even if the EU ETS allowance prices decline. CCfDs can help stabilize revenue streams enough for investors to secure lower financing costs and ensure commercial viability . 76

  60. Why is it relevant? Effect of CCfD on financing structure and total cost of production In the case of the breakthrough technology without a CCfD the uncertainty of CO 2 prices in addition to the usual revenue uncertainty needs to be covered by additional expensive equity. A CCfD reduces the expected CO 2 price that is required for the technology to break- even because it allows for the use of more debt to pay for the investment and thus reduces the overall financing cost as compared to the case without a CCfD. Climate Strategies (2019) 77

  61. Why is it relevant? Illustration of the ‚ valley of death ‘ concept relative to technology readiness CCfD would close an important gap in the support landscape, and be especially well suited for technologies transitioning from the Research & Development (R&D) phase to large-scale commercial deployment and at risk of stranding in the so- called “ Valley of Death ”. This instrument would thus help to support the large-scale commercialization of key breakthrough industry technologies with a large GHG mitigation potential. These key technologies include direct- reduction of steel using green hydrogen and specific carbon capture and storage applications. Other relevant areas include process innovations related to CCU, optimization of product design and material PWC substitution. 78

  62. Illustration: How a Carbon Contract for Difference could help finance new low-carbon key technologies Illustration of the policy mechanism of the Carbon Contract for Difference Source: Agora Energiewende, 2019

  63. Illustration: How a Carbon Contract for Difference could help finance new low-carbon key technologies Example of how a CCfD could work to support commercial-scale investments in first-of-a-kind decarbonised basic materials production O. Sartor, IDDRI (2019) 80

  64. CCfD Design Considerations CCfDs largely target support for OPEX. A carbon price floor or additional instruments targeting project-specific CAPEX, or energy supply infrastructure can be used complementarily. CCfDs can be implemented as a double-sided instrument. The “double sided” nature of the CCfD limits the likelihood of unjustified ‘windfall profits’ being generated. Furthermore, auctions can be used to make sure the most cost-effective projects meeting key criteria are selected. CCfD are effective as long as CO 2 -intensive technologies are cheaper than innovative low- emissions technologies due the failure to adequately price their externalities. The effectiveness of CCfDs is therefore limited to the phase of introducing innovative technologies to the market. A support period can, therefore, be limited to specific time period (eg. 15-20 years). CCfDs can be introduced at both a national and EU level, and complementary financing via both national budgets and the EU budget (eg. the EU Innovation Fund) is also possible. Policy-makers can choose to only provide CCfDs to projects aligned with carbon neutrality objective by setting strict project qualification criteria. 81

  65. How much would it cost? Total cost scenario estimates of a CCfD for cement, steel & aluminium in France Support for a CCfD for low-carbon materials would be smaller compared to RES support. Estimates by IDDRI for France show that, even for relatively low range of carbon price scenarios during the next 20 years, i.e. between 35- 45€, the total cost for a country the size of France would be quite small, ranging from 100-500 million € /yr in the highest volume scenario to as low as 42 million €/ yr in the low volume scenario. Reasons include: 1) relevant basic materials markets are much smaller than the domestic energy market; 2) the CCfD can be restricted only to first-of-a-kind commercial projects; 3) the Treasury would pay (or receive) only the difference between the strike price and the actual observed EU ETS price. IDDRI 2019 82

  66. The combination of the following 3 policy instruments is a viable option for closing the investment gap for breakthrough technologies with a CCfD 1.) Revision of the EU ETS Directive New low-carbon production facitilities still need to get free allocation of EUA for a limited amount of time based on the product benchmarks of the CO2-intensive production plant that was replaced (e.g. 1.6 EUA per t of steel). Sales of these EUA generate one stream of income to cover additional costs. New low-carbon production facilities do not (fully) count towards reducing the benchmarks for conventional production plants (top-runner approach) 2.) A Carbon Contract for Difference (CCfD) The CfD pays the financial gap between the CO2-Price in the EU ETS and the required CO2-Price for a low-carbon production plant. This creates another stream of income to cover additional costs. 3.) A Climate surcharge on end products A climate surcharge is levied on end products containing basic materials, irrespective of their production method and location (green, grey, domestic, import). Costs for end consumers are small. 83

  67. Illustration: How a Carbon Contract for Difference could be financed by a consumption charge on end products Policy mechanism to compensate for additional costs of green steel production through CfD along on the steel value chain Source: ETC, 2018 84

  68. Compatibility with State Aid Rules The EEAG do not mention CCfDs but tools are there to assess compatibility: Measures aimed at increasing environmental protection in the absence of EU standards. Eco-innovation : the mechanism for CCfDs would only be designed to support first-of-a-kind commercial scale projects. CCfDs would be an extension of EU R&D&Innovation policy. Aid intensity: 50% for large enterprises with eco-innovation bonus, or 100% if competitive tenders . At European-level, a CCfD system could be set up under Art. 10a paragraph 8 of the ETS Directive, which establishes an EU Innovation Fund with 400 million certificates foreseen to be auctioned to finance projects aimed at reducing GHG emissions – e.g. CCU & CCS. Funding granted from the EU Innovation Fund would be automatically considered State Aid compatible. 85

  69. Considerations with regards to use and design of competitive auctions Sartor, O. (2019) reflects on the design of competitive tenders: Financial Risks: Poorly designed auctions risk windfall profits due to an asymmetry of information about the true cost of technologies or tendering outcomes resulting from insufficient competition. Cost mitigation options: • require expert third party independent verification of incremental cost estimates of the project • have eligible projects bid for a strike price set at a relatively conservative level. make the tender open to enough basic material uses that currently have a high carbon footprint • embedded in the materials (e.g. construction) to ensure sufficient competition. Potential eligibility criteria: a) Capacity to replace significant volumes of high-carbon primary materials for the relevant usage; b) Consistency with national long-term decarbonisation strategy ; c) Economic justification (i.e. does the project face an incremental cost compared to alternatives?); d) Cost per unit of CO2 reduced ; e) Social, environmental or economic co-benefits. 86

  70. Stakeholder feedback on the EEAG with regards to support for climate-neutral technologies and applications More generally, several stakeholders suggests that the GBER, EEAG and R&D&I guidelines do not provide a sufficiently clear and reliable framework to scale climate-neutral technologies and propose to create a new chapter for climate-neutral technologies and applications under the EEAG that is consistently included in the GBER. This chapter could include: • Setting up a fast-track notification procedure climate-neutral projects. For example, notification thresholds for climate neutral technologies should be increased to € 200mn with the possibility of an ex -post control mechanism for the European Commission. • Clear and ambitious provisions on sandboxing which cover, inter alia, a state aid exemption, that create more legal certainty about how industrial-scale sandboxes could be implemented. • Increasing aid intensity for climate-neutral technologies in first-of-its kind large scale installation to 100%. • Streamlining and clarifying the existing rules for the cumulation of aid , including a provision that generally allows the cumulation of aid for climate-neutral technologies. 87

  71. Reflections (1) The funding of operational costs together with capital investment needs to be strengthened within the new state aid framework for many breakthrough technologies to become viable. CCfDs could play a key role in securing lower financing costs and ensuring the commercial viability for key breakthrough technologies needed to achieve a climate-neutral industry Future state aid guidelines should provide an appropriate framework to enable the development of CCfDs by Member States either by developing a chapter explicitly devoted to this instrument in the EEAG, or clarifying the scope of their application in a new chapter for climate- neutral technologies and applications. The risk of asymmetry of information and low competition mean that in many cases competitive auctions may not be well suited as a mechanism for determining support rates or come at the expense of significantly limiting the scope of the application of CCfDs as an instrument. 88

  72. Reflections (2) CCfDs are not a silver bullet for reducing GHG-emissions from basic materials industries. Additional instruments will be needed to enable large-scale financing of basic materials production and to tackle parts of the problem that CCfDs do not fully address (eg. carbon leakage protection). With regards to financing and carbon leakage protection, a carbon consumption charge (climate contribution) raised on consumers of basic materials combined with continued free allocation may from a political and governance perspective be more easily feasible than the introduction of a border carbon adjustment, full auctioning of CO2 allowances and use of EU ETS revenues. If this system is chosen, it should be clarified within the framework of the EEAG that it is allowed to combine aid with free allocation for projects enabling emission reductions. Specific regulatory barriers will still need to be removed (Eg. the cement sector cannot currently sell certain low carbon cement alternatives as cement under certain EU cement standards). Key infrastructure (eg. CCS transport & storage) is also still missing. Encouraging adequate investment in this infrastructure will require additional support frameworks. 89

  73. Carbon Capture, Utilisation and Storage (CCUS) 90

  74. Carbon Capture and Storage – State Aid rules Directive 2009/31 on the geological storage of carbon dioxide EEAG, section 3.6 on CC S : CCS contributes to the common objective of environmental protection Beneficiaries: fossil fuel and biomass power plants; industrial installations equipped with CCS Commission presumes that aid to CCS addresses a residual market failure (economic gap between the CO2 price and cost of CCS technology does not incentivise investment in CCS) Both operating and investment aid are permitted Article 107(3)(c) TFEU for CC U Framework for State aid for research and development and innovation (2014) GBER, Article 25 - Aid for research and development projects (no specific mention of CCS) 91

  75. Stakeholder feedback on the EEAG with regards to CCS With regards to CCS, the EEAG provisions are generally considered clear and appropriate. However, stakeholders have suggested specific provisions be revised to ensure greater clarity: The EEAG should be revised to provide clarity that waterborne/shipping/ship-based CCS solutions for transporting CO2 for permanent storage, as in the case of the Northern Lights project, are eligible for State aid to prevent difficulties in accessing public funding. The definition of CCS should be clarified to ensure it includes CCS associated with natural gas steam methane reforming plants to produce blue hydrogen. The definition of permanent CO2 storage should be defined more broadly to include approaches to safely storing CO2 other than geological formations. The current EEAG are written in a way that envisages the CCS projects being carried out within the same company responsible for the carbon emissions as an integrated project, with capture, transport and storage all being performed within one project. The Guidelines should be revised to reflect alternative business models with disaggregated value chains. 92

  76. Stakeholder feedback on the EEAG with regards to CCU, DAC An explicit framework beyond CCS is needed to include CCU and DAC with CCS State aid should be permissible for companies providing a service to another company while not realizing an environmental effect by its own activities (eg. CCU with CO2 captured for a greenhouse) If included, the eligibility of CCU should refer to life-cycle emissions criteria to ensure that state funded CCU projects contribute to GHG emission reductions and not only circularity. 93

  77. Case studies / The Netherlands – Investment aid for CO2 capture and pipelines Investment aid to (1) Meerlanden for the installation of CO 2 capture technology enabling the removal of CO 2 from flue gases at its biomass digester facility; (2) Zuidplaspolder, (3) de Kwakel and (4) OCAP (PrimA4a area) to build CO 2 pipelines, compressor and reduction station. The captured CO 2 will be fed into a network and transported to greenhouses where it is to be used . Objective : Increase environmental protection by reducing the use of primary energy sources for conventional forms of CO2 generation for horticultural processes and by reducing CO 2 emissions linked to the horticultural process, by avoiding that greenhouses use natural gas for CO 2 production. Legal framework : 107(3) TFEU! (1) the EEAG do not cover CCU ; (2) the increase of environmental protection is achieved by the end consumers, not at the beneficiary‘s level who „do not reduce its own pollution “. Despite that „ The capturing of the CO 2 and its transfer to the greenhouses also avoids that MEERLANDEN’s CO 2 emissions are released into the atmosphere.” Necessity for aid: remedy the funding gap of the investment: costly infrastructure, low CO 2 revenues, lack of coordinated cooperation between suppliers and consumers. Cumulation with Energy Investment Deduction : no for Meerlanden ≠ yes for Zuidplaspolder, de Kwakel and Prim4a 94

  78. Case studies / Front End Engineering and Development studies (UK 2009 & 2013 and Norway 2017) FEED studies aim to reduce the technical, environmental and financial risks of CCS projects. Advantage : (1) FEED studies enable the beneficiaries to stay in the competition for the final contract for the UK CCS project. (2) They provide the beneficiaries with additional know-how that they can use commercially as ‘first movers’, e.g. to compete for further CCS projects. Outside scope of EEAG: do not result directly in capturing CO2 & are not environmental studies Objective: CCS commercialisation in line with the targets laid down in the Roadmap 2050 towards the development of commercial-scale CCS technology + environmental protection. Appropriateness : (1) making CCS mandatory is not an option given the high risks and costs associated with such projects. (2) Supporting FEED studies rather than the final CCS project enables to compare the environmental and technical aspects of both studies and thus to choose the project with the best 'value- for money’. (3) the EPS will not by itself incentivise investment in CCS. Proportionality: Fund only activities that are genuinely required for the purposes of reaching the Final Investment Decision. Plans to reach agreement as to the precise nature of all FEED activities prior to the commencement of funding and scrutinise all costs + maximum aid intensity of 75%. July 2019: call for CCU demonstration projects: projects must fall within the GBER Article 25 95

  79. Case studies / Norway “The Norwegian CCS strategy encompasses a wide range of activities, including research, development and demonstration , work on the realisation of large-scale demonstration facilities, transport, storage and alternative use of CO2 and efforts to promote CCS on a global scale. (…) the first CCS projects [shall] serve as reference projects and generate the greatest possible amount of knowledge and that they establish necessary infrastructure, thereby contributing to the further deployment and dissemination of large-scale CCS internationally. Moreover, the success of the first projects may stimulate CCS deployment on a commercial basis . (…) An important part of the strategy is the Norwegian Government's ambition to realise at least one full-scale CCS demonstration project by 2020 .” (EFTA, decision 16 March 2017 on FEED studies) 96

  80. Case studies/ CCS projects in Norway 2008: Capital injection for construction and ownership of the Test Centre Mongstad, a post- combustion plant including an oil refinery and a combined heat and power plant, equipped with post- combustion CCS technologies, intended to test, verify and demonstrate CCS. Non-compliance with MEIP : TCM project was meant to operate for 5 years and no profit was foreseeable in such a short term. There were “not sufficient information available for the moment to assess whether the TCM constitutes a project of common European interest ”. EFTA did not give criteria for qualification. Objective : likely to contribute as a preliminary phase to the full chain demonstration of CCS. 2018: Norways looking for (EU?) financing for equipping cement plant and waste incineration facility with CCS. In the demonstration phase, the CO2 captured at a cement plant and a waste incineration facility in Norway would be stored temporarily on site in big containers before it is shipped off the Norwegian coast for injection deep beneath the seabed. 97

  81. State aid case studies: Norway Source: Euractiv 98

  82. Reflections Little number of projects or even FEED studies submitted under State aid rules: lack of take off of the technology in the EU. In any case, it seems to be admitted that CCS/U projects cannot be achieved without EU or State support. The scope of the EEAG is restrictive: CCU is excluded; FEED studies are not covered (the use GBER art. 25 is capped by EUR 20 million/undertaking/project for industrial research). GBER Art. 48 on energy infrastructure would not apply to CCS/CCU. 99

  83. Conclusion on CCS CCS is/was politically almost dead in Germany and has a very tough road ahead in Europe. However, limited technology options place CCS at the forefront of the cement industry’s net -zero strategy and negative emissions are essential to reach the targets under the Paris agreement. Parts of the CCS technology chain could be developed under the umbrella of CCU. But the technology is very expensive and the mitigation potential limited. In other sectors, CCS could become a “bridge” technology that is required because other options are delayed or too expensive in the mean time. Politically, von der Leyen’s Green Deal and the EU’s pledge for carbon neutrality open up a window of opportunity to make substantial progress in developing a comprehensive European CCS strategy within the next year. The Sustainable Europe Investment Plan intends to support investment in scaling up CCS/CCU via the Innovation Fund. Whatever the result, CCS policy support efforts should not be pursued in isolation, but rather embedded in a broader decarbonization strategy, in particular with regards to the industrial sector. 100

Recommend


More recommend