high marginal tax rates on the top 1
play

High Marginal Tax Rates on the Top 1%? Lessons from a Life Cycle - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

High Marginal Tax Rates on the Top 1%? Lessons from a Life Cycle Model with Idiosyncratic Income Risk Fabian Kindermann Dirk Krueger University of Bonn and Netspar University of Pennsylvania, CEPR, CFS, NBER and Netspar Seminar at Queens


  1. High Marginal Tax Rates on the Top 1%? Lessons from a Life Cycle Model with Idiosyncratic Income Risk Fabian Kindermann Dirk Krueger University of Bonn and Netspar University of Pennsylvania, CEPR, CFS, NBER and Netspar Seminar at Queens University October 2019 Kindermann, Krueger Top Marginal Taxes June 2019 1 / 53

  2. Motivation: Income Share of Top 1 % in the U.S. Top 1 Percent Income Share in the United States 25% 20% 15% 10% 5% Top 1% income share excluding capital gains Top 1% income share including capital gains 0% 1913 1920 1927 1934 1941 1948 1955 1962 1969 1976 1983 1990 1997 2004 2011 Source: Source is Piketty and Saez (2003) and the World Top Incomes Database. Notes: The fj gure reports the share of total income earned by top 1 percent families in the United States More on the Top 1% Kindermann, Krueger Top Marginal Taxes June 2019 2 / 53

  3. Motivation: Top Marginal Income Tax Rates Top Marginal Income Tax Rates, 1900 – 2011 100% 90% 80% 70% 60% 50% 40% 30% US UK 20% France Germany 10% 0% 1900 1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 Source: Piketty and Saez (2013, fj gure 1). Notes: The fj gure depicts the top marginal individual income tax rate in the United States, United Kindermann, Krueger Top Marginal Taxes June 2019 3 / 53

  4. Motivation • Large secular increase in earnings, income and wealth inequality: increasing share of the ”Top 1%” • Popular and scientific calls for increasing marginal tax rates at the top, e.g. Diamond and Saez (2011), Reich (2010), Piketty (2014) Kindermann, Krueger Top Marginal Taxes June 2019 4 / 53

  5. Motivation • Large secular increase in earnings, income and wealth inequality: increasing share of the ”Top 1%” • Popular and scientific calls for increasing marginal tax rates at the top, e.g. Diamond and Saez (2011), Reich (2010), Piketty (2014) • Scientific basis: Diamond/Saez (2011): Revenue maximizing top marginal tax rate above fixed income threshold ¯ y : 1 τ h = 1 + a · ǫ 1 • a = y ) measures thickness of tail of income distribution 1 − 1 / ( y m / ¯ • ǫ : Average elasticity of earnings (in top bracket) w.r.t. d log( y ) e : net of tax rate ǫ = d log(1 − τ ) • Generalization to dynamic models: Badel and Huggett (2016) • Diamond/Saez estimates: a = 1 . 5 and ǫ = 0 . 25 → τ h = 0 . 73 maximizes tax revenue from top 1% earnings More on the Formula Kindermann, Krueger Top Marginal Taxes June 2019 4 / 53

  6. Details of the Formula (relevant for this paper) • Static model of labor supply. Labor productivity e distributed Pareto with tail parameter a e in population. • Constant marginal tax rate τ above threshold ¯ y. Discard revenue. • Peak of the Laffer curve if ¯ y is held fixed (alternatively, if share of population subject to top marginal rate -say top 1%- fixed): 1 1 τ 1% τ h = and = h 1 + a · ǫ 1 + ǫ where � � ǫ = 1 1 − 1 a · ǫ u + · ǫ c a • Assume preferences given by U ( c, n ) = c 1 − γ 1 − γ − λ n 1+1 /χ 1 + 1 /χ Kindermann, Krueger Top Marginal Taxes June 2019 5 / 53

  7. Details of the Formula (continued) a e • Suppose γ = 0: No income effects. Then ǫ u = ǫ c = χ, a = 1+ χ and 1 1 τ 1% τ h = and = 1 + χ, h 1 + a · χ 1 − γ 1 • With income effects ( γ > 0): Then ǫ u = γ +1 /χ , ǫ c = γ +1 /χ and τ 1% = τ 1% τ h = τ h ( χ, γ, a e ) and h ( χ, γ, a e ) h • Basic upshots: • Exact tax experiment important: τ h vs τ 1% h . • (Obviously) Frisch labor supply elasticity χ important. • Size of the income effect (parameterized by γ ) important. • Labor productivity process e at the top (through a e ) important. Kindermann, Krueger Top Marginal Taxes June 2019 6 / 53

  8. Objective of this project • Evaluate Diamond/Piketty/Saez recommendations in a (relatively standard) heterogeneous households macro model • Key ingredients of the analysis: • Life cycle model with endogenous labor supply, savings decisions • Incomplete markets and general equilibrium • Ex ante and ex post heterogeneity: Redistribution vs. Insurance • Progressive tax schedule that adjusts to changes in τ h • Maximization over tax-reform-induced transition paths: Kindermann, Krueger Top Marginal Taxes June 2019 7 / 53

  9. Objective of this project • Evaluate Diamond/Piketty/Saez recommendations in a (relatively standard) heterogeneous households macro model • Key ingredients of the analysis: • Life cycle model with endogenous labor supply, savings decisions • Incomplete markets and general equilibrium • Ex ante and ex post heterogeneity: Redistribution vs. Insurance • Progressive tax schedule that adjusts to changes in τ h • Maximization over tax-reform-induced transition paths: • Evolution of wealth distribution and factor prices over time • Welfare impact on transitional generations • Key challenge: How to generate realistic earnings and wealth distribution at the top 1%? → We use rare but large labor productivity shocks not observed in survey data (Castaneda/Diaz-Gimenez/Rios-Rull, 2003) More on Related Literature Kindermann, Krueger Top Marginal Taxes June 2019 7 / 53

  10. Central Result I: Revenue Maximization • Peak of Laffer curve from top 1% earners is at higher marginal tax rates ( τ h = 87%) than advocated by Diamond and Saez. • Intuition: • Productivity realizations at the very top large, persistent (but not permanent) • Given calibrated preferences, individuals at the very top of productivity distribution maintain labor supply even at very high marginal tax rates ⇒ Uncompensated elasticity of earnings w.r.t. tax rate is low at the top (strong income effects). Kindermann, Krueger Top Marginal Taxes June 2019 8 / 53

  11. Central Result II: Welfare Maximization • Revenue maximizing τ h = 87% rate is not welfare maximizing, but not that far off. Social welfare maximized at τ h = 79%. • Intuition: High tax progressivity • is detrimental for macro aggregates • lower capital stock • lower wages • hurts the top 1% who receive weight in social welfare function • but provides social insurance against never making it into Top 1%. Kindermann, Krueger Top Marginal Taxes June 2019 9 / 53

  12. The Model: Overview • Large-scale OLG model as in Auerbach and Kotlikoff (1987) • Neoclassical production sector • Life cycle structure with population growth, retirement age j r , uncertain survival, terminal age J • Consumption-savings, labor supply decisions s.t. idiosyncratic wage risk (Bewley, Huggett, Aiyagari, Imrohoroglu, Kaplan and Violante) • Wage is given by e ( j, s, α, η ) w • Preferences U ( c, n ) = c 1 − γ 1 − γ − λ n 1+1 /χ 1 + 1 /χ • Benevolent government (values transitional generations) • Chooses optimal (within parametric class) progressive labor income tax reform τ h , τ l and required time path of government debt B t . • Takes other elements of fiscal policy as fixed τ c , τ k , τ ss . Kindermann, Krueger Top Marginal Taxes June 2019 10 / 53

  13. The Model Households: Labor productivity • Households are ex ante and ex post heterogeneous w.r.t. labor productivity • Wage is given by w · e ( j, s, α, η ): • Wage rate of the economy w • Deterministic education level s ∈ { n, c } determined at birth • Deterministic age component ǫ j,s • Fixed effect α determined at birth • Stochastic component η following education specific Markov chain with states η ∈ E s and transition matrix π s ( η, η ′ ). Kindermann, Krueger Top Marginal Taxes June 2019 11 / 53

  14. The Model Households: Decision making • At each point in time households choose • consumption c • labor supply n and thus earnings y = w · e · n • savings in the risk free asset a at return r n = r (1 − τ k ) and with tight borrowing constraint • Preferences U ( c, n ) = c 1 − γ 1 − γ − λ n 1+1 /χ 1 + 1 /χ Kindermann, Krueger Top Marginal Taxes June 2019 12 / 53

  15. The Model Households: Decision making • At each point in time households choose • consumption c • labor supply n and thus earnings y = w · e · n • savings in the risk free asset a at return r n = r (1 − τ k ) and with tight borrowing constraint • Preferences U ( c, n ) = c 1 − γ 1 − γ − λ n 1+1 /χ 1 + 1 /χ • Dynamic optimization problem: � π s ( η ′ | η ) v ( j + 1 , s, α, η ′ , a ′ ) v ( j, s, α, η, a ) = c,n,a ′ ≥ 0 U ( c, n ) + βψ j +1 max η ′ (1 + τ c ) c + a ′ + T ( y ) + T ss ( y ) = (1 + r n ) a + b ( j, s, α, η ) + y Kindermann, Krueger Top Marginal Taxes June 2019 12 / 53

  16. The Model Households: Decision making • At each point in time households choose • consumption c • labor supply n and thus earnings y = w · e · n • savings in the risk free asset a with tight borrowing constraint • Preferences U ( c, n ) = c 1 − γ 1 − γ − λ n 1+1 /χ 1 + 1 /χ • Dynamic optimization problem: � π s ( η ′ | η ) v ( j + 1 , s, α, η ′ , a ′ ) v ( j, s, α, η, a ) = c,n,a ′ ≥ 0 U ( c, n ) + βψ j +1 max η ′ (1 + τ c ) c + a ′ + T ( y ) + T ss ( y ) = (1 + r n ) a + b ( j, s, α, η ) + y Kindermann, Krueger Top Marginal Taxes June 2019 13 / 53

Recommend


More recommend