differentiated durable goods
play

Differentiated Durable Goods Monopoly and Competition Nava and - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Differentiated Durable Goods Monopoly and Competition Nava and Schiraldi London School of Economics March 2018 Nava (LSE) Differentiated Durable Goods Mar 18 1 / 74 Focus: Differentiated Durable Goods We study the incentives to


  1. Differentiated Durable Goods Monopoly and Competition Nava and Schiraldi London School of Economics March 2018 Nava (LSE) Differentiated Durable Goods Mar 18 1 / 74

  2. Focus: Differentiated Durable Goods We study the incentives to differentiate products when goods are sold over time and without commitment. The results on the monopoly : characterize limiting outcomes in terms of a simple static problem ; deliver a robust Coase conjecture for all multi-product settings; develop insights on product design . The results on the competition show why: competition can unambiguously increase market power ; such instances arise when competitors choose products. Nava (LSE) Differentiated Durable Goods Mar 18 2 / 74

  3. Coase Conjecture 1972 Coase’s seminal conjecture first raised the time consistency problem: Upon selling to high value buyers, a monopolist cannot stop selling. If so, prices keep falling and forward looking buyers expect this. But if so, buyers are unwilling to pay a high price in the first place. As the time between offers vanishes, the opening price converges to its lowest valuation and the competitive quantity is sold in a twinkle of an eye . Formal proofs in Stokey 1981; Fudenberg, Levine, Tirole 1985; Gul, Sonnenschein, Wilson 1986; Asubel, Deneckere 1989 established that: Varieties Gap MC MC Time Efficient Competitive Unique 1 No Yes Infinite Yes MPE Folk 1 Yes Yes Finite Yes Yes PBE Nava (LSE) Differentiated Durable Goods Mar 18 3 / 74

  4. Monopoly: Related Literature The more recent literature on durable goods monopoly has analysed: The robustness of Coase’s insight to changes in the assumptions. 1 Bond-Samuelson 1984; Kahn 1986; Ausubel-Deneckere 1989; Bagnoli-Salant-Swierzbinski 1989; Sobel 1991; Fehr-Kuhn 1995; Biehl 2001; Takeyama 2002; Hahn 2006; Inderst 2008; McAfee-Wiseman 2008; Deb 2011; Montez 2013; Ortner 2014; Board-Pycia 2014. Tactics that could be used to avoid the commitment problem. 2 Bulow 1982; Butz 1990; Levinthaland-Purohit 1989; Waldman 1993; Choi 1994; Waldman 1996; Fudenberg-Tirole 1998; Lee-Lee 1998. Many of these studies are cast as violations of the Coasian conclusion. Nava (LSE) Differentiated Durable Goods Mar 18 4 / 74

  5. Monopoly: Contributions In the monopoly case we establish that: Static and dynamic market-clearing prices coincide. 1 Optimal market-clearing profits bound PBE profits from below. 2 Mixing may be required on-path to conceal discounts . 3 Limiting MPE profits converge to optimal market-clearing profits . 4 Robustness of these conclusions to alternative specifications. 5 Product design implications. 6 Equilibrium pricing is neither minimal, nor competitive, nor efficient . But, the Coasian logic survives in that optimal market-clearing and agreement govern pricing . Nava (LSE) Differentiated Durable Goods Mar 18 5 / 74

  6. Competition: Related Literature The seminal contribution on competition by Gul 1987 : considers markets in which firms produce the same product ; proves a Folk theorem as an incumbent may benefit from entry. These anti-competitive insights however: rely on high discount factors to sustain collusion; apply only when products are not differentiated; do not extend to stationary equilibria . Nava (LSE) Differentiated Durable Goods Mar 18 6 / 74

  7. Competition: Contributions Competition increases market power if the present value of profits of every seller is higher than in their respective monopoly setting. With differentiated products , competition can increase market power: in all PBE even in stationary equilibria ; regardless of the value the discount factor . In the competition case we: find conditions for competition to increase market power in all PBE; 1 endogenize the choice of products in a location choice model; 2 show that this naturally leads to increased in market power. 3 Nava (LSE) Differentiated Durable Goods Mar 18 7 / 74

  8. Model Nava (LSE) Differentiated Durable Goods Mar 18 8 / 74

  9. Model: The Monopolist The time is countably infinite, t ∈ { 0 , 1 , ... } . A single firm operates in the market in every period. Two varieties , a and b , of a durable good can be produced and sold. At each time period the monopolist sets prices for the two varieties p = ( p a , p b ) . The marginal cost of producing units of each variety is zero . The monopolist discounts the future with a discount factor δ . Its payoff amounts to the present discounted value of future profits. Nava (LSE) Differentiated Durable Goods Mar 18 9 / 74

  10. Model: Buyers All buyers have unit-demand for the durable good. Buyers exit the market upon purchasing any one variety. There is a unit measure of buyers. Buyers are characterised by their values for the two products v = ( v a , v b ) . Value profiles are private information of buyers. Buyers discount the future by the common factor δ . The payoff of consuming variety i at price p i at date t amounts to δ t − 1 ( v i − p i ) . Nava (LSE) Differentiated Durable Goods Mar 18 10 / 74

  11. Model: Buyers’ Values A measure F on the unit square [ 0 , 1 ] 2 describes the distribution of values. Let F be the associated cumulative and V be the support. Let F i be the marginal cumulative of variety i and V i be its support. Definitions (Regularity Assumption) The market is said to be regular if: V is convex; F is absolutely continuous on R 2 ; its density f satisfies f ( v ) ∈ ( f , f ) for any v ∈ V . The monopolist knows F , but not the value of a given buyer. Nava (LSE) Differentiated Durable Goods Mar 18 11 / 74

  12. Model: Information and Solution Concepts Players observe for every previous period: the prices posted by the monopolist; (possibly) the total measure of buyers for each variety. At any history, a strategy: for the monopolist specifies a profile of prices. for an active buyer specifies which variety to purchase, if any. Let A t be the set of active buyers at a given history h t . Those buyers who have yet to purchase a variety at date t . Our results characterize the measurable PBE of this game. MPE are PBE in which buyers’ strategy depends only on current prices . Nava (LSE) Differentiated Durable Goods Mar 18 12 / 74

  13. Optimal Market Clearing Nava (LSE) Differentiated Durable Goods Mar 18 13 / 74

  14. Static Demand Functions Momentarily consider the static version of the model. Given prices, the static demand for product i amount to d i ( p ) = F ( v i − p i > max { v j − p j , 0 } ) . Nava (LSE) Differentiated Durable Goods Mar 18 14 / 74

  15. Static Market Clearing Prices A market clearing price is a price profile that clears the market. Let M be the set of market clearing prices � � p ∈ R 2 | max i { v i − p i } ≥ 0 for any v ∈ V M = . Independence Concordance Discordance Nava (LSE) Differentiated Durable Goods Mar 18 15 / 74

  16. Static Optimal Market Clearing An optimal market clearing price ¯ p solves the following static problem max p ∈ M [ d a ( p ) p a + d b ( p ) p b ] . The value ¯ π of this program is the optimal market clearing profit . Nava (LSE) Differentiated Durable Goods Mar 18 16 / 74

  17. Static Market Clearing: Minimal Values Let w i denote the minimal value of variety i in the support V . Let w g denote the minimal value of the durable good w g = min v ∈ V max { v a , v b } . Clearly it must be that w g ≥ max { w a , w b } . w g = 0 w g = 0 w g > 0 Nava (LSE) Differentiated Durable Goods Mar 18 17 / 74

  18. Static Market Clearing: Special Cases Varieties are identical if v a = v b for all v ∈ V . Varieties are ranked if they are not identical and v i ≥ v j for all v ∈ V . Varieties are unranked if for any i there is v ∈ V such that v i > v j . Identical Ranked Unranked Nava (LSE) Differentiated Durable Goods Mar 18 18 / 74

  19. Static Optimal Market Clearing: Minimal Pricing Lemma Optimal market-clearing profits: (1) weakly exceed w g ; (2) strictly exceed max i w i if varieties are unranked; (3) equal min i w i if and only if varieties are identical; (4) equal 0 if and only if varieties are identical and ( 0 , 0 ) ∈ V . Nava (LSE) Differentiated Durable Goods Mar 18 19 / 74

  20. Static Optimal Market Clearing: Minimal Pricing Lemma Optimal market-clearing profits strictly exceed w g : (5) if varieties are ranked and w a = w b ; (6) if varieties are independently distributed and w a = w b . Nava (LSE) Differentiated Durable Goods Mar 18 20 / 74

  21. Some Intuition: OMC Lemma Let w a ≥ w b , OMC profits: amount to w a at the MC price p = ( w a , 1 ) ; can thus amount to w b only if w a = w b = w ; amount to w at the MC price ( p i , p j ) = ( w + e , w ) only if d i ( w + e , w ) = F ( v i − v j > e ) = 0. Nava (LSE) Differentiated Durable Goods Mar 18 21 / 74

  22. Static Optimal Market Clearing: Efficiency A price is efficient if every buyer purchases its preferred variety. Fact Optimal market-clearing prices are inefficient: (1) if varieties are ranked and w a = w b ; (2) if varieties are independently distributed and w a = w b . Nava (LSE) Differentiated Durable Goods Mar 18 22 / 74

  23. Static Optimal Market Clearing: Comments In contrast to the 1-variety case, market-clearing no longer implies that: profits amount to the minimal value of a variety or of the good; pricing is efficient or at the minimal value of varieties or of the good; profits equal 0 when there are no gaps and ( 0 , 0 ) ∈ V . Nava (LSE) Differentiated Durable Goods Mar 18 23 / 74

  24. Coase Conjecture Nava (LSE) Differentiated Durable Goods Mar 18 24 / 74

Recommend


More recommend