bidding strategies for fantasy sport auctions
play

BIDDING STRATEGIES FOR FANTASY-SPORT AUCTIONS BY ANAGNOSTOPOULOS - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

BIDDING STRATEGIES FOR FANTASY-SPORT AUCTIONS BY ANAGNOSTOPOULOS ET AL. Alireza Amani Hamedani Sepehr Mousavi Introduction Absence of Nash equilibrium Fair-Price Bidding 2 Type of online game Participants as virtual managers of


  1. BIDDING STRATEGIES FOR FANTASY-SPORT AUCTIONS BY ANAGNOSTOPOULOS ET AL. Alireza Amani Hamedani Sepehr Mousavi

  2. § Introduction § Absence of Nash equilibrium § Fair-Price Bidding 2

  3. § Type of online game § Participants as virtual managers of professional athletes § Choosing players and modifying rosters over the course of a season § Fantasy points obtained based on statistical performance of the athletes in actual games 3

  4. § Fantasy Points § Converted athlete statistics from real-life games § Calculation § Manually by league commissioner § Online platforms tracking game results 4

  5. § Users (team managers) add, drop, and trade athletes over the course of the season § In response to changes in athletes’ potentials § Pivotal event is the player draft § Initiates the competition 5

  6. § Multi-billion dollar industry § In 2017, 59.3 million users in the USA and Canada § On average, fantasy sport players spend $556 over a 1-year period 6

  7. Fig 1. Number of Fantasy Sports Users by Year (in millions) in the USA and Canada 7

  8. § Snake vs Auction § Snake Draft § Teams taking turns choosing players based on pre-determined order § Once each round is over, the draft snakes back on itself § Used in majority of fantasy leagues 8

  9. Fig 2. Snake draft with 12 teams and 15 rounds 9

  10. § Auction Draft § Each team has an initial budget and each player has a price § The number of rounds mirrors the number of roster spots § Instead of drafting a player in your turn, you place a player on the auction block and start the bidding at an amount of your choice. § Focus of this paper 10

  11. § Fantasy sports league composed of: § 𝑙 team managers , or users , with 3 ≤ 𝑙 ≤ 20 § 𝑣 ( , 𝑣 * , … , 𝑣 , § 𝑜 athletes (or players ) § 𝑄 ( , 𝑄 * , … , 𝑄 / § Each team composed of 𝑛 athletes § Depends on the sport and fantasy games provider 11

  12. § Snake vs Auction § Choice made by the initiator of the league § Snake Draft § No bidding or competition, just a pre-determined order of teams to draft 12

  13. § Auction Draft § Fixed budget of 𝐶 § Managers taking turns successively, in some pre-determined order, nominating athletes for bidding via an English auction § Default bid is $1. Can be raised higher within the budget § Managers given a fixed amount of time to place higher bid 13

  14. § Auction Draft § Leftover money cannot be used § Managers should be able to complete their rosters § Each athlete has a fixed position and each team must meet a fixed distribution of positions § Depends on the sport and fantasy games provider 14

  15. § Simplifying assumptions § Team managers agree on the value of every athlete. § Each athlete 𝑄 2 has an associated value 𝑤 2 § 𝑤 2 : Expected number of fantasy points 𝑄 2 will earn throughout the season § 𝑤 2 is a shared belief, common to all managers 15

  16. § Simplifying assumptions § Auction draft is a sealed-bid auction § Arbitrary fractional bids § In case of a tie, athlete is given out with equal probability § Exception when all managers place the minimal bid. Athlete given to nominating manager 16

  17. § Simplifying assumptions § For each position the player pool has exactly the number of athletes required to complete each team § 𝑜 = 𝑙𝑛 § Fair share: / 𝑊 = 1 𝑙 7 𝑤 2 28( 17

  18. § Pure strategy subgame perfect Nash equilibria do not generally exist in the fantasy auction model § 9 : worst case with athletes automatically nominated in decreasing order of their values § 9 (; worst case for the general case in which nominations are made in a general adaptive fashion according to manager strategies 18

  19. § Due to competitive and strategic environment, it is natural to take game theoretic approach. § Generally there will not even exist any pure strategy subgame perfect equilibria in fantasy draft auctions 19

  20. § Example: § Two users with equal budgets § Each team roster has two slots § Four athletes, two of unequal positive value, and two of value 0 § Claim: In the above example, if the lower (positive) value athlete is nominated first, there exists no pure strategy Nash equilibrium forward from that point 20

  21. § Simple but not good approach § Generalized good approach § Fair-Price bidding in arbitrary nomination order 21

  22. § Define fair share of total value as below: § Define fair price for athlete 𝑄 2 : § 22

  23. § Not a good result in this case: 9((C,F>F) § 𝑤 ( = 𝑤 * = ⋯ = 𝑤 ,>( = 𝑊 1 − 𝜁 𝑏𝑜𝑒 𝑤 , = 𝑤 ,C( = … = 𝑤 ,D = ,D>,C( § The value of the final team for our manager: 23

  24. § § Expected value of the final team at least 9 : with 𝛽 = 1.5 § Regardless of the other managers’ bidding strategies 24

  25. § Valuable athletes with 𝑤 2 ≥ 9 L § Three scenarios: One valuable athlete is bought 1. No valuable athlete, at least at one point, not enough budget 2. No valuable athlete, always sufficient budget 3. 25

  26. Expected value: 9 L 𝑞 1. At that point, the value at least 9 *L . So, Expected value: 9 *L 𝑞 N 2. Expected value: 𝑌𝑞 NN and, 3. 26

  27. 27

  28. § Examples for other 𝛽 that lead to a result of almost 9 : § How to come up with a lower bound for any 𝛽 ? 28

  29. § Three parameters: 𝛾 > 𝛽 ≥ 1 𝑏𝑜𝑒 𝛿 ≥ 1 § Two groups: 29

  30. § Case 1: Value of group 𝑀 is larger than 𝑇 § Put all the budget for group 𝑀 30

  31. 31

  32. § Case 2: § Average value per spot: § For available spots, choose an athlete when 𝑄 2 in 𝑀 , or 𝑄 2 in 𝑇 and 32

  33. § Complex proof § Under choices 𝛽 = (; : , 𝛾 = 8 𝑏𝑜𝑒 𝛿 = 2, Expected value is 9 (; 33

  34. § Results hold for private-value case § The big question: How to fill in the gap between our result and the best one can hope for. § May be competitive in real life! 34

  35. 35

Recommend


More recommend