a reexamination of contingent convertibles with stock
play

A Reexamination of Contingent Convertibles with Stock Price Triggers - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

A Reexamination of Contingent Convertibles with Stock Price Triggers George Pennacchi and Alexei Tchistyi 1 16 th Annual FDIC/JFSR Banking Research Conference 9 September 2016 1 Both from Department of Finance, University of Illinois. Contingent


  1. A Reexamination of Contingent Convertibles with Stock Price Triggers George Pennacchi and Alexei Tchistyi 1 16 th Annual FDIC/JFSR Banking Research Conference 9 September 2016 1 Both from Department of Finance, University of Illinois.

  2. Contingent Convertibles (CoCos) � CoCos or “contingent capital” are debt issued by banks that convert to shareholders’ equity or have a principal write down when a triggering event occurs. � As envisioned by Flannery (2005), CoCos would convert to a pre-specified number of new equity shares when the bank’s stock price declines to a pre-specified level. � CoCos are potentially valuable for stabilizing individual banks and the financial system. They have the advantages of � debt during normal times (tax advantages, possible lower agency costs). � equity during times of stress by reducing the costs of financial distress and bankruptcy.

  3. Time of Conversion � For CoCos to be effective in stabilizing banks as going-concerns, they need to convert to new equity at the onset of a bank’s financial distress. � All CoCos issued thus far have conversion triggers linked to a regulatory (book value) capital ratio, typically a core Tier 1 capital to risk-weighted assets ratio of 7%. � Unfortunately, regulatory capital ratios fail to signal distress in a timely manner and tend to be manipulated upward when banks face stress. 2 2 See Mariathasan and Merrouche JFI (2014), Begley et al. (2015), and Plosser and Santos (2015).

  4. Tier 1 Capital to Debt Ratios Prior to Lehman Failure (Haldane, 2011)

  5. Market Value of Equity to Debt Prior to Lehman Failure (Haldane, 2011)

  6. Market Value Triggers � A market value (e.g., the bank stock price) trigger appears capable of converting CoCo at the onset of distress � However, some policymakers and academics have become skeptical of market value triggers. � In part, their distrust derives from the analysis of Sundaresan and Wang (SW) JF 2015 who conclude that basing a CoCo trigger on the bank’s stock price leads to: � multiple equilibria for the stock price when conversion terms favor CoCo investors. � no equilibrium for the stock price when conversion terms favor the bank’s initial shareholders. � Economists at international and national bank supervisory authorities cite SW and multiple equilibria as a disadvantage of market value CoCo triggers. 3 3 E.g., Avdjiev et al (2013) and Leitner (2012).

  7. Our Paper � We consider the same modeling framework as SW and Glasserman and Nouri (GN) (2012), except that while they both focus on CoCos that have a finite maturity, we study CoCos that can be perpetuities (have a perpetual maturity). � We find: 1. there is a unique stock price equilibrium when conversion terms favor CoCo investors, confirming GN and identifying a mistake in SW’s proof that explains their different result. 2. there is never a stock price equilibrium when conversion terms favor shareholders and CoCos have a finite maturity. 3. for realistic parameter values, there is a unique stock price equilibrium when conversion terms favor shareholders and CoCos have a perpetual maturity. � Thus, whether a CoCo has a perpetual versus finite maturity is critical for a well-defined stock price equilibrium.

  8. Importance of Our Main Result � In practice, perpetual maturity CoCos appear to be the standard, rather than the exception. � Berg and Kaserer (2015) and Avdjiev et al. (2015) document that the majority of CoCos issued thus far are perpetuities. � In part this is due to the Basel III requirement that CoCos be perpetuities to qualify as “Additional Tier 1” capital.

  9. Model Assumptions: Bank Assets � A bank’s assets generate cashflows, a t , that are paid out to claimants and satisfy the risk-neutral process da t = µ a t dt + σ a t dz � An implication is that the value of the bank’s assets, A t , equals A t = a t / ( r − µ ) where r > µ is the risk-free interest rate. Thus, the risk-neutral process for A t is dA t = µ A t dt + σ A t dz

  10. Model Assumptions: Bank Liabilities � The bank initially has three types of liabilities: 1. Perpetual senior debt with principal B that pays a continuous coupon at rate b . 2. n shares of equity (capital) with date t market price per share S t (if it exists). 3. CoCos with principal C that pay a continuous coupon at rate c and convert to m new shares of equity when S t first falls to the trigger level L . � Regulators close the bank the first time assets fall to bB / r , making senior debt default-free.

  11. Dividends and Conversion Terms � Note that dividends paid per share equal [( a t − bB − cC ) / n ] dt prior to conversion and [( a t − bB ) / ( n + m )] dt after conversion. � Also note that CoCo conversion terms favor � CoCo investors when mL > cC / r . � the bank’s initial shareholders when mL < cC / r .

  12. Hypothetical “Post-Conversion” Bank � Consider an identical bank with no CoCos but n + m shares of equity. � Its stock price per share is � � 1 A t − bB U t = n + m r � Define A uc as U ( A uc ) = L . Then A uc = L ( n + m ) + bB r is the level of assets at which the stock price equals L .

  13. Definition of an Equilibrium Conversion and Stock Price � Let τ δ = inf { A t ≤ bB / r } be the bank’s closure (bankruptcy) date. Definition: A pair of a conversion time, ˆ τ , and a pre-conversion per-share equity value, ˆ S t , is an equilibrium if ˆ τ is a stopping time adapted to the filtration generated by the Brownian motion z t such that � � t ∈ [ 0 , ∞ ) : ˆ τ = inf ˆ S t ≤ L , and � � τ δ � 1 ˆ E Q t e − r ( s − t ) S t = 1 { s ≤ ˆ n ( a s − bB − cC ) τ } t � � 1 + 1 { s > ˆ n + m ( a s − bB ) ds . τ }

  14. Equilibrium Link to Post-Conversion Bank Lemma 1: For any stopping time ˆ τ adapted to the filtration generated by Brownian motion z t , ˆ S t is continuous in t. � Since information is continuous, the stock price cannot jump. � Let τ uc = inf { t ∈ [ 0 , ∞ ) : A t ≤ A uc } be the first time the post-conversion bank’s stock price equals the trigger level L . Proposition 1: If there is an equilibrium, then conversion happens when A t = A uc , that is, τ = τ uc = inf { t ∈ [ 0 , ∞ ) : A t ≤ A uc } . ˆ � Since the stock price cannot jump, conversion must occur at the time when the post-converion bank’s stock price first equals the trigger level L .

  15. “Candidate” Stock Price for CoCo-Issuing Bank � Given that ˆ τ = τ uc when an equilibrium exists, if there exists an equilibrium then the pre-conversion stock price must be: � � τ uc � 1 e − r ( s − t ) ( a s − bB − cC ) ds nE Q = S t ( A t ) t t � � τ δ � 1 τ uc e − r ( s − t ) ( a s − bB ) ds n + mE Q + t

  16. Solution for Candidate Stock Price � The candidate stock price prior to conversion can be simplified to � � � − γ � � − γ � � A t � A t S t = 1 A t − bB r − cC 1 − − mL n r A uc A uc where   �� � 2 γ ≡ 1  µ − 1 µ − 1 2 σ 2 +  > 0 . 2 σ 2 + 2 r σ 2 σ 2 � While it is generally the case that a firm’s stock price is increasing with the value of assets, it might not always be the case in our setting of a bank issuing CoCos.

  17. Conditions for Stock Price to Increase with Assets Lemma 2 : If one of the following is true: (i) mL ≥ cC or r (ii) mL < cC and r σ 2 ≥ 2 ( r + µγ ∗ ) γ ∗ ( 1 + γ ∗ ) , bB where γ ∗ ≡ r + L ( n + m ) , or equivalently cC r − Lm γ cC − bB L ≥ r ( n + ( 1 + γ ) m ) , then S t ( A uc ) = L and S t ( A t ) is strictly increasing in A t for all A t ≥ A uc . Otherwise, S t ( A t ) < L for some A t > A uc .

  18. Conditions for a Unique Stock Price Equilibrium Theorem 1 : When either condition (i) or (ii) in Lemma 2 is satisfied, then there exists a unique equilibrium in which conversion of CoCos happens when the asset level drops to A uc for the first time and the equilibrium stock prices per share before and after conversion are given by � � � − γ � � − γ � � A t � A t S t = 1 A t − bB r − cC 1 − − mL n r A uc A uc and � � 1 A t − bB S t = U t = , n + m r respectively. When neither condition (i) nor (ii) in Lemma 2 is satisfied, then there is no equilibrium .

  19. Implication for CoCo Value � An implication of Theorem 1 is that when condition (i) or (ii) in Lemma 2 is satisfied, the value of the CoCo prior to conversion is A t − bB C t = r − nS t � � � A uc � γ cC mL − cC = r + r A t � The CoCo’s value is greater ( less ) than an equivalent � � mL − cC non-convertible bond when the conversion terms r favor ( disfavor ) the CoCo investors.

  20. Graphical Proof of Theorem � Our illustrations use the following parameter values: Parameter Value Senior Debt Principal, B 90 Senior Debt Coupon, b 3.2% CoCo Principal, C 5 CoCo Coupon, c 3.6% Initial Equityholder Shares, n 1 CoCo Conversion Shares, m 1 0.0% 4 Risk-neutral Cashflow Growth, µ 4.0% 5 Volatility of Asset Returns, σ Risk-free Interest Rate, r 3.0% 4 Implies that dividends decline to zero at the time the bank is closed. 5 2003-2012 average for Bank of America, Citigroup, and JPMorgan Chase.

  21. Conversion Terms Favor CoCo Investors, mL=8 > cC/r=6

  22. Conversion Terms Favor Shareholders, mL=4 < cC/r=6 but (ii) Holds

  23. Conversion Terms Favor Shareholders, mL=4 < cC/r=6 but (ii) Does Not Hold σ = 0 . 25 %

Recommend


More recommend