public finance and development tim besley and torsten
play

Public Finance and Development Tim Besley and Torsten Persson - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Public Finance and Development Tim Besley and Torsten Persson Handbook Conference Berekely, December 2011 It is shortage of resources, and not inadequate incentives, which limits the pace of economic development. Indeed the importance of


  1. Public Finance and Development Tim Besley and Torsten Persson Handbook Conference Berekely, December 2011

  2. “It is shortage of resources, and not inadequate incentives, which limits the pace of economic development. Indeed the importance of public revenue from the point of view of accelerated economic devel- opment could hardly be exaggerated.” Nicholas Kaldor, ‘Taxation for Economic Development,” Journal of Modern African Studies , 1963, page 7 “The fiscal history of a people is above all an essential part of its general history. An enormous influence on the fate of nations emanates from the economic bleeding which the needs of the state necessitates, and from the use to which the results are put.” (Joseph Schumpeter, The Crisis of the Tax State , 1918)

  3. Motivation • Long tradition of viewing raising tax revenues a constraint on development as well as the product of under-development. • The key challenge is to understand how a state can go from raising around 10% tax in GDP to around 40% • Large literature but interest in such issues is episodic. • Tax administration and compliance are central issues.

  4. Our Approach • Key concept is a state’s fiscal capacity, ii.e. its ability to generate revenues. • We model this as dynamic investments which introduce new tax bases and expand the scope of others. • The following chart illustrates one aspect of this:

  5. Fiscal capacity in a sample of 73 countries 1 .8 Proportion of Countries .6 .4 .2 0 1800 1850 1900 1950 2000 Year Income Tax VAT Figure 1: Historical evolution of fiscal capacity

  6. Outline 1. Background facts 2. Model of fiscal capacity investment 3. Use framework to discuss: (a) economic structure (b) political institutions (c) social structure

  7. (d) demand for public goods (e) non-tax revenues (f) compliance technologies

  8. (Stylized) Facts Stylized Fact 1: Rich countries have made successive investments in their fis- cal capacities over time. Stylized Fact 2: Rich countries collect a much larger share of their income in taxes than do poor countries Stylized Fact 3: Rich countries rely to a much larger extent on income taxes as opposed to trade taxes than do poor countries. Stylized Fact 4: High-tax countries rely to a much larger extent on income taxes as opposed to trade taxes than do low-tax countries.

  9. Stylized Fact 5: Rich countries collect much higher tax revenue than poor countries despite comparable statutory rates.

  10. (Stylized) Facts • These appear to be cross-sectional and time series facts • We use data from an (unofficial) IMF source for cross section • Data on time series for twentieth century come from Mitchell (2007) — we are conservative in picking a sample of 18 countries where data is reliable and comparable over time. — The countries in this sample are Argentina, Australia, Brazil, Canada, Chile, Colombia, Denmark, Finland, Ireland, Japan, Mexico, Nether- lands, New Zealand, Norway, Sweden, Switzerland, United Kingdom, and the United States.

  11. Ev olution of tax revenue and income tax f or a sample of 18 Countries Average share of tax in aggregate income .3 .6 Average share of Income Tax .2 .4 .1 .2 0 0 1900 1920 1940 1960 1980 2000 Year Tax revenue in aggregate income (lef t scale) Share of income tax in rev enue (right scale) Figure 2: Taxes and share of income tax over time

  12. A. Country-level taxes and income B. Global-level taxes and income .5 .5 5 year averages of share of taxes in GDP .4 .4 Share of taxes in GDP (1999) .3 .3 .2 .2 .1 .1 0 0 6 7 8 9 10 11 6 7 8 9 10 11 Log GDP per capita in 2000 5 year averages of log GDP per capita High income in 2000 Mid income in 2000 1900-39 1940-49 1950-69 Low income in 2000 Fitted values 1970-99 Fitted values Figure 3: Tax revenue and GDP per capita

  13. A. Country-level income and trade taxes by GDP B. Global-level income and trade taxes by time period .8 .8 5 year averages of share of income tax .6 .6 Share of income taxes (1999) .4 .4 .2 .2 0 0 0 .2 .4 .6 0 .2 .4 .6 Share of trade taxes (1999) 5 year averages of share of trade tax High income in 2000 Mid income in 2000 1900-39 1940-49 1950-69 Low income in 2000 Fitted values 1970-99 Fitted values Figure 4: Income taxes and trade taxes

  14. A. Country-level income taxes and total taxes by GDP B. Global-level income taxes and total taxes by time period .8 .8 5 year averages of share of income tax .6 .6 Share of income taxes (1999) .4 .4 .2 .2 0 0 0 .1 .2 .3 .4 .5 0 .1 .2 .3 .4 .5 Share of taxes in GDP(1999) 5 year averages of share of taxes in GDP High income in 2000 Mid income in 2000 1900-39 1940-49 1950-69 Low income in 2000 Fitted values 1970-99 Fitted values Figure 5: Income taxes and total taxes

  15. 80 Top Statutory Income Tax Rate in 1990s 60 40 20 0 0 .1 .2 .3 .4 .5 Share of Taxes in GDP (1999) High income in 2000 Mid income in 2000 Low income in 2000 Fitted values Figure 6: Top statutory income tax rate and total tax take

  16. Framework • Population with J distinct groups, denoted by J = 1 , ... J , and where group J is homogenous and comprises a fraction ξ J of the population. • Two time periods s = 1 , 2 . • N + 1 consumption goods, indexed by n ∈ { 0 , 1 , ..., N } . • Consumption of these goods by group J in period s are denoted by x J n,s . • A public good g s .

  17. • Individuals in group J supply labor, L J s , and choose how to allocate their income across consumption goods. • Small open economy with pre-tax prices of p n,s . • Wage rates ω J s are potentially group-specific and variable over time.

  18. Taxation • Government may levy taxes on goods/labor except the non-taxed nu- meraire good 0 • Post-tax price of each good is: p n,s (1 + t n,s ) , n = 1 , 2 , .., N , while the net wage is: � � ω J 1 − t L,s s � � • Let t s = t 1 ,s , ..., t N,s , t L,s be the vector of tax rates.

  19. • Tax payments to the government: � � p n,s x J t n,s n,s − e n,s , • Main interpretation of e n,s is consumption/labor supply in the informal sector. • This is assumed to be costly c ( e n,s , τ n,s ) , where c is increasing and convex in e n,s . • Parallel expression for labor taxes � � ω J t L,s s L s − e L,s � � with cost c e L,s , τ L,s .

  20. Fiscal-capacity investments • Costs of non-compliance depend on investments in fiscal capacity τ s = � � τ 1 ,s , ..., τ N,s , τ L,s • For each tax base, k = 1 , ..., N, L , we assume: > 0 and ∂ 2 c ( e n,s , τ n,s ) ∂c ( e n,s , τ n,s ) ≥ 0 , ∂τ n,s ∂e n,s ∂τ n,s such that greater fiscal capacity makes avoiding taxes more difficult. • Assume c ( e n,s , 0) = 0

  21. • Investment cost is: F k ( τ k, 2 − τ k, 1 ) + f k ( τ k, 2 , τ k, 1 ) fork = 1 , ..., N, L, for investing in dimension k of fiscal capacity. • First part of the investment cost function F k is convex in τ k, 2 , , with ∂ F k (0) ∂τ k, 2 = 0 , i.e., the marginal cost at zero is negligible. • May be fixed-cost component (paid once) � f k ≥ 0 if τ k, 1 = 0 and τ k, 2 > 0 f k ( τ k, 2 , τ k, 1 ) = 0 if τ k, 1 > 0 .

  22. • Let L � F k ( τ k, 2 − τ k, 1 ) + f k ( τ k, 2 , τ k, 1 ) F ( τ 2 , τ 1 ) = k =1 be the total costs of investing in fiscal capacity.

  23. Household decisions • Preferences are quasi-linear and given by: � � � � x J x J 1 ,s , .., x J L J + α J 0 ,s + u − φ s H ( g s ) . s N,s where u is a concave utility function and φ the convex disutility of labor. • α J s parametrizes the value of public goods. • Individual budget constraint: N � x J p n,s (1 + t n,s ) x J 0 ,s + n,s n =1 L � � � � �� � ω J L J s + r J ≤ 1 − t L,s s + t k,s e k,s − c e k,s , τ k,s . s k =1

  24. • r J s is a group-specific cash-transfer. • Standard condition for choice of e k,s � � e ∗ t k,s = c e k,s , τ k,s for k = 1 , ..., N, L if τ k,s > 0 . (1) � � • e ∗ t k,s , τ k,s decreasing in the fiscal capacity investment, tax base by k,s tax base. • Household “profits” from non-compliance: � � � � = t k,s e k,s − c q t k,s , τ k,s e k,s , τ k,s , which are increasing in t k,s and decreasing in τ k,s .

  25. • Let L � � � Q ( t s , τ s ) = q t k,s , τ k,s k =1 be the aggregate per-capita profit from efforts devoted to tax-reducing � � activities where t s = t 1 ,s , ..., t N,s , t L,s is the vector of tax rates. • Indirect utility function V J � � � � � � t s , τ s , g s , ω J s , r J = v ( p 1 1 + t 1 ,s 1 + t N,s ) , ..., p N,s s � � + v L ( ω J 1 − t L,s ) (2) s + Q ( t s , τ s ) + α J s H ( g s ) + r J (3) s

  26. The policy problem • Let N J � � ξ J t L,s ( ω J s L J B ( t s , τ s ) = t n,s ( p n,s x n,s − e n,s ) + s − e L,s ) n =1 J =1 be the tax revenue from goods and labor. • Government budget constraint: J � ξ J r J B ( t s , τ s ) + R s ≥ g s + s + m s , (4) J =1

  27. where � F ( τ 2 , τ 1 ) if s = 1 m s = 0 if s = 2 is the amount invested in fiscal capacity (relevant only in period 1) and R s is any (net) revenue from borrowing, aid or natural resources.

  28. • Social objective: J µ J ξ J V J � � � t s , τ s , g s , ω J s , r J s J =1 where � J J =1 µ J ξ J = 1 and µ J is a Pareto weight.

Recommend


More recommend